Otwarty dostęp

Queuing to leave: A new approach to immigration


Zacytuj

Introduction

In 2015, 1.83 million irregular migrants arrived at Europe's external borders.

http://www.europarl.europa.eu/thinktank/infographics/migration/public/index.html?page=migration (Accessed September 12, 2018)

They came primarily from countries facing political unrest in the Middle East and Northern Africa. The spate of revolutions known as the Arab Spring began around December 2010 but immigration from the region peaked much later in 2015. With this context of the highest migration flows since World War II, my paper applies an alternative framework to understand the dynamics of legal and illegal immigration and looks at the effect of violent conflict on both channels.

The central idea of this research is that illegal immigration emerges out of stringent controls in the parallel legal system. This idea is also contained in work by Auriol and Mesnard, 2016 where the authors consider the eligibility criteria of legal channels as “rationing mechanisms” that generate an illegal counterpart. Using a different methodology based on queuing systems (QS), my paper seeks to formalize this theory and present some empirical substance on it. Despite much journalistic attention, the current migration crisis has not received its due in academic work as yet. Further, the canonical models of migration are not specifically suited for crises of the sort recently witnessed and those that may arise in future due to political instability or climate change.

The QS framework is ideal for scenarios of shortage as it allows for two simultaneous allocation mechanisms – the price and the waiting cost to acquire the good or service (Sattinger, 2002). The theoretical framework in this paper focuses on the latter, such that the waiting cost of migration is proportional to the magnitude of people wanting to migrate (Jasso et al., 2010). This allows individual migration choices to be dependent on the traffic or magnitude of people trying to migrate at a given time. Further, due to additional frictions caused by immigration policies, potential migrants may trade-off higher returns from legal immigration for the lower waiting costs and easier access from illegal entry. I consider three cases to depict frictions in the legal queue for immigration that are set by the host country: an arbitrary rejection rate, a minimum waiting time criteria that each migrant must meet, and a capacity limit on the total number of migrant applications. These immigration policy regimes have real-world counterparts, often in combination with each other. In the first two cases, the migrant chooses the number of attempts to migrate legally and the amount of time spent waiting to migrate, respectively. These endogenous choices vary based on overall traffic in the system, exogenous policy parameters, and individual time-preferences. Using simple comparative-statics results, I can thus identify the effects of changes in the legal QS on flows in the parallel illegal queue. I find that increased traffic, i.e., more people trying to immigrate, greater stringency in legal immigration, and higher levels of impatience to immigrate, all lead to an increase in illegal immigration flows. The third scenario illustrates a case of fixed immigration quotas set by the host country wherein the migrant cannot choose to remain in the QS for legal immigration once the limit capacity is reached. This baseline queuing model of immigration does not consider heterogeneity among migrants but instead focuses only on changes in the parameters that characterize the legal and illegal channels of immigration. Under perfect information, migrants would conceivably sort into many separate QS of her own “type,” where the parameters would reflect that specific type. Such separation of queues is common, for example by skill, origin-country, or capital investments.

Refer to Martin and Midgley (2015) for a detailed description of different immigrant categories in the US.

Due to the lack of data at the individual migrant level to illustrate the theoretical model, I apply a reduced-form empirical strategy using aggregate flows of legal and illegal immigration into the Schengen region. Aggregated annual data on legal migration is available from Eurostat; similarly, the number of detected illegal border-crossings (IBCs), disaggregated by migrants’ country of origin, is available from the European Agency for the Management of Operational Cooperation at the External Borders of the Member States of the European Union (Frontex).

Frontex is the European Agency for the Management of Operational Cooperation at the External Borders of the Member States of the European Union, which records the number of detected IBCs via land and sea routes into the Schengen region.

Applying a generalized method of moments (GMM) approach, I look at the effect of origin-country violent conflict on legal and illegal immigration into the Schengen region. Conflict has been shown in related literature to increase the number of people willing to migrate (Bohra-Mishra and Massey, 2011), as well as alter individuals’ time preferences, making them more impatient (Voors et al., 2012). As suggested by the queuing theory framework, the empirical section finds that violent conflict leads to an increase in illegal immigration and has no effect on legal immigrant flows. Further, I use the dynamic panel-data setting to examine spillovers between both types of immigration flows and persistence within each. I find evidence of positive spillovers from legal immigration flows to undocumented migration but not vice-versa. These findings, however, are not structural results but still illustrative of the model's predictions.

This paper draws from and contributes to three branches of literature: (i) the economics literature on migration – which has focused on its causes and effects, along with optimal immigration policy, (ii) the impact of conflict on migration, and (iii) the literature on the application of queuing theory to economic phenomena.

Firstly, this paper adds to the vast literature on immigration choices. In my reading, I distinguish between studies that deal with the choice to migrate or not,

This includes classical work on the expected-wage hypothesis (Harris and Todaro, 1970; Todaro, 1969) and theories of missing markets and relative deprivation (Stark, 1984; Stark and Levhari, 1982; Katz and Stark, 1986). More structuralist theories have been put forward by Massey (1988) and Piore (1980), which emphasize the nature of immigrant-labor markets and capitalist expansion to explain migrants’ flows from “peripheral” to “core” countries. This literature has received empirical traction in Lewer and Van den Berg, 2008 by using a gravity model. An excellent classification of the causes of migration is given by Massey et al. (1993). Recent work has built an evidence base of the trends and magnitudes of international immigration, with attention to its gender and skill dimensions (Docquier et al. [2009, 2007]).

and those that deal with choices subsequent to that initial decision. The latter refers to choices of destination (Grogger and Hanson, 2011; Munshi, 2003), route, mode and duration. My paper also falls in this latter category as I take the decision to migrate as a given starting point and focus only on the choice between legal and illegal channels. It is related to extensive work by Djajić (2014), who looks at asylum seekers’ choice between undocumented migration or the United Nations Refugee Agency (UNHCR) resettlement programs and the optimal duration of transit between source countries and the migrant's final destination (Djajić and Vinogradova, 2017; Djajić, 2017).

Analyses of the “effects” of immigration on host country populations or optimal policy responses are beyond the scope of this paper, as I focus on immigrant choices. Dustmann et al. (2016) provide an extremely cogent review and critique of the empirical specifications used in recent works. Studies on the “effect” of immigration on host populations are characterized by contradictory empirical findings – some have found negative effects (Borjas, 2003) while others almost no effects (Card, 1990, 2009) or even benefits (Ottaviano and Peri, 2012; Chassamboulli and Peri, 2015). This and an earlier review of the “effect” literature, Friedberg and Hunt, 1995, find more support against negative effects of immigration on host populations. The economics literature on migration has also focused on optimal immigration policy (Benhabib and Jovanovic, 2012) and Meyers (2000) gives a non-technical classification and summary of migration policy theory.

A pioneering paper on immigration policy is by Ethier (1986). Also see Djajić and Michael (2014).

With regard to the ongoing refugee crisis, a relevant and contemporary policy background and description of ground realities is given by Dustmann et al. (2017). While I do not study the issue of optimal immigration policy from the host-country's perspective, it is necessary to incorporate the feedback costs of increased traffic and illegal immigration as a result of stringent acceptance rates or waiting-time criteria.

I thank an anonymous reviewer for comments related to this.

The Dublin Regulation states that asylum seekers must apply for refugee status in the first European country they enter – placing a large part of the processing burden on Europe's southern border countries. Although European Union (EU) countries have agreed to common principles, there is great variance in the waiting time and acceptance rates across countries, depending on processing capacity, migrant origin-country, and political pressure in the host-country (Connor, 2017). One omission in the migration literature that I try to address is the influence of “heavy traffic” or large flows of people trying to migrate at the same time on migrant choices. Most existing works focus on individual decisions between alternative channels and neglect the effect of the magnitude of flows in one channel on the other.

The second contribution of this paper is to examine the impact of conflict on migration, where the economics literature is as yet relatively sparse. Political scientists have, on the other hand, contributed much to this issue (Davenport et al., 2003; Neumayer, 2005; Bohra-Mishra and Massey, 2011).

However, some empirical methods suffer from ‘kitchen-sink’ techniques and, in the case of panel analysis, do not account for the Nickell bias and the general problem of endogeneity.

Substantial literature in economics and conflict deals with the effect of conflict on income growth (Rodrik, 1999; Davis and Weinstein, 2008, 2002) often via individual components of the production function (Humphreys [2003]). Research in Sierra Leone by Bellows and Miguel (2006, 2009) looks at the effect of civil-war on institutions and individuals’ political participation. A related but novel study in Burundi by Voors et al. (2012) looks at how conflict influences time and risk preferences. The authors find that even temporary shocks, such as conflict, can lead to persistent changes in behavior, making people more pro-social, risk seeking, and impatient, thereby altering savings and investment decisions. However, there is limited work in economics on the effect of source-country conflict on migration flows and how the effect differs between legal and illegal channels. This is another omission that this paper tries to address.

Finally, this paper aims to add to the growing literature in economics using queuing theory. Queuing theory involves the study of input and service processes along specific disciplines, e.g., first-come-first-serve.

This field of study has its origins in the works of Erlang (1909) to study telephone exchanges.

The seminal contributions in economics are by Naor (1969) and Lui (1985) to describe the optimal provision of public goods and bribery, respectively. Market models based on queuing can operate in or outside of equilibrium unlike Walrasian models. An important application of queuing theory has been to search and matching models in labor markets (Sattinger, 2010; Stevens, 2007). The scope of this paper extends to conceptualizing immigration as a QS with an “in-between” or waiting period, during which the migrant incurs costs. This liminal feature of immigration has not received due attention in the literature.

In anthropology, the concept of liminality has been used to characterize subjects undergoing transformative and ‘in-between’ experiences (Gennep, 1960; Turner, 1987).

Some notable exceptions are works by Djajić (2014, 2017), Friebel and Guriev (2006), Hainmueller et al. (2016), and Tamura (2010).

In Section 2 of this paper, I present the theoretical framework of two parallel queues for legal and illegal immigration. The section considers three different immigration policy regimes chosen by the host country. Section 3 and 4 provide a reduced-form empirical strategy to illustrate the model and its results, respectively. The final section concludes with possible extensions and limitations of my work.

Theoretical Framework

I begin by explaining the intuition behind the theory, which can be easily understood without formal proofs. Consider migration as occurring along two parallel channels or queues, one of which is legal and the other is illegal, respectively denoted by subscripts l and i (Figure 1). Migrants enter the QS and are processed for travel by immigration authorities in the legal channel or by migrant smugglers in the illegal channel, according to some stochastic processes. In the legal queue, migrants are either rejected or accepted based on some exogenous destination-country criteria.

Successful exit from the QS means acceptance for the journey and not necessarily entry into the destination country. While undocumented immigration is not necessarily successful, there are fewer (or no) criteria to fulfill to undertake the journey other than monetary payment.

These criteria reflect the stringency of legal immigration and are illustrated in the following cases that I will examine in detail:

An arbitrarily fixed rate of acceptance ν ⋲ [0,1] in the legal channel, (i.e., (1 − ν) share of all entrants are not accepted to travel legally).

A minimum waiting period (Wlc) \left( {W_l^c} \right) that the migrant should spend in the queue to be allowed legal entry.

A finite limit K on the number of migrants allowed within the legal QS.

Figure 1

Migration Queuing System (Cases I and II).

In Cases I and II, if migrants are unsuccessful in the legal channel, they can re-enter the legal queue and attempt again or they can enter the parallel illegal QS where acceptance is guaranteed but less-preferred. In Case III, migrants above the quota are diverted automatically to the illegal queue. In each of these stylized cases, migrants are not endowed with personalized attributes. In this respect, a specific QS can refer to a particular category of migrants and there may exist multiple such systems for each type of migrant (e.g., skilled and unskilled). The results in the following cases pertain to how changes in queue parameters influence choices of migrants who share the same observable characteristics. I proceed by using some established results from queuing theory (Medhi [2002]) and perform simple comparative statics analyses where feasible. All three aforementioned cases characterizing stringency in legal migration illustrate the central idea that ceteris paribus, larger flows of illegal migration arise out of greater legal stringency.

Case I
Assumption 1

Both the legal and illegal queues consist of a Poisson arrival process with parameters λl and λi, respectively. Inter-service times (i.e., time between processing each migrant) are exponentially distributed such that the average intensity of services per unit time are μl and μi, with μl < μi.

The rate of service in the illegal channel may be better characterized as a function of the rate of entry, i.e., μi = μi(λi) since smugglers adapt to demand for their services. I avoid this notation for tractability and the already standing assumption that μi > λi. This assumption needs to hold to ensure that the QS is not explosive.

This is denoted in Kendall's notation as an M/M/1 queue where the M stands for Markovian and I restrict attention to a single or centralized server in each channel for simplicity. The average arrival rate of migrants to the legal queue is the sum of the rate of initial entry (λo) and re-entry (λr) into the legal queue, i.e., λl = λo + λr. The corresponding average rate of arrivals to the illegal queue (λi) will be discussed later. This setup also assumes no balking, i.e., once a migrant decides to migrate, she does not leave the QS but only chooses among the two channels and the number of attempts to make in the legal queue.

This assumption does not change the main implications of the model because comparing the expected utility between legal and illegal migration to a third alternative (of not migrating) would not change the preferences between the first two. For further reference, Yue et al., 2009 relax this assumption and present model performance indicators using numerical simulations.

Service discipline is first-in-first-out (FIFO).

Now, I define Pn as the probability of there being n people in the QS. In the steady state, the rate up from n to n + 1 people in the queue must be equal to the rate down from n + 1 to n: (λo+λr)pn=μlpn+1(stabilitycondition) \left( {{\lambda _o} + {\lambda _r}} \right){p_n} = {\mu _l}{p_{n + 1}}\,\,\, ({\rm stability\, condition}) where the rate of re-entry is λr = (1 − ν)μlλi: i.e., the total proportion of migrants who are unsuccessful [(1 − ν)μl] minus the fraction who switch over to the illegal queue (λi). Queuing theory allows us to calculate standard performance indicators, such as the expected number of migrants in the legal QS (refer to Appendix A2). E(Ql)=1+ρνλiμlνρ+λiμl(wheretrafficisρ=λoμl) \matrix{ {E\left( {{Q_l}} \right) = {{1 + \rho - \nu - {{{\lambda _i}} \over {{\mu _l}}}} \over {\nu - \rho + {{{\lambda _i}} \over {{\mu _l}}}}}} \hfill & {\left( {{\rm{where}}\,'{\rm{traffic}}'\,{\rm{is}}\,\rho = {{{\lambda _o}} \over {{\mu _l}}}} \right)} \hfill \cr }

Eq. (2) gives the expected length 〈Q〉 and we can then calculate the expected waiting time 〈Wl〉 of the queue for legal migration. E(Ql)=(λo+λr)E(Wl)(usingLittle'slaw:Q=λW) \matrix{ {E\left( {{Q_l}} \right) = \left( {{\lambda _o} + {\lambda _r}} \right)E\left( {{W_l}} \right)} \hfill & {\left( {{\rm{using}}\,{\rm{Little}}'{\rm{s}}\,{\rm{law}}:\left\langle Q \right\rangle = \lambda \left\langle W \right\rangle } \right)} \hfill \cr } E(Wl)=1μl(νρ+λiμl) E\left( {{W_l}} \right) = {1 \over {{\mu _l}\left( {\nu - \rho + {{{\lambda _i}} \over {{\mu _l}}}} \right)}}

Assumption 2

The queuing system is stable with positive expected waiting times and queue length. This is contained in the condition ρ<ν+λiμl \rho < \nu + {{{\lambda _i}} \over {{\mu _l}}} holding.

This assumption follows from a technical requirement for the first moments of the queue content (Eq. (2)) and waiting time (Eq. (4)) to be positive and to ensure that the queue is stable, i.e., does not explode. When this is violated, we cannot conduct comparative statics deriving from the stability condition, as the queue increases infinitely. Intuitively, the condition imposes that on average, the traffic in the legal queue must be less than the rate at which migrants exit the QS by being accepted or by switching into the illegal queue.

Migrants have a planning horizon [0,T] and incur a cost C per unit of time that they remain in their origin countries. All migrants are taken to be exponential discounters with a discount rate α. The cost C may be thought of as an opportunity cost or the cost of facing negative circumstances in their home country (such as conflict, unemployment, famine, etc.). The cost is incurred in both legal and illegal queues while the migrant is “waiting” to leave. The cost and discount rate are the same for all migrants in the QS. Benefits from successfully exiting the legal and illegal QS are mRl and Ri per unit of time respectively (Rl > Ri), where m is the maximum number of attempts made to migrate. The key idea behind this requirement is that “something” is gained even from unsuccessful attempts; it may be in the form of experience or know-how about the destination country, which yields higher rewards once the destination is reached. There is no rejection in the illegal QS and all agents are accepted for the journey in their first attempt. Benefits from exiting each queue successfully are the same for all migrants.

The benefits (Rl and Ri) can be conceived as expected benefits of reaching the destination country safely net of the traveling costs, inclusive of risk differentials. While legal travel is almost certain to deliver the migrant to the destination country, it is not so for illegal journeys.

The optimization problem involves choosing the maximum number of attempts (m) the migrant makes to travel legally. The total expected return to a migrant who makes m attempts to migrate legally is the expected return from failing all m times (first term of Eq. (5)) plus the expected return from failing (m − 1) times and succeeding in the mth try (second term of Eq. (5)).

Migrants only make an additional attempt if they have failed in all previous attempts. Further, the ‘no balking’ assumption implies that λo is given. This—along with migrant homogeneity—rule out binding credit constraints for all entrants into the QS.

E[Ul(m(λi),λi)]=(1ν)mC0mWleαtdt+(1ν)m1ν[mRlmWlTeαtdtC0mWleαtdt] E\left[ {{U_l}\left( {m\left( {{\lambda _i}} \right),\,{\lambda _i}} \right)} \right] = - {\left( {1 - \nu } \right)^m}C\int\limits_0^{m\left\langle {{W_l}} \right\rangle } {{e^{ - \alpha t}}dt + {{\left( {1 - \nu } \right)}^{m - 1}}\nu \left[ {m{R_l}\int\limits_{m\left\langle {{W_l}} \right\rangle }^T {{e^{ - \alpha t}}dt - C\int\limits_0^{m\left\langle {{W_l}} \right\rangle } {{e^{ - \alpha t}}dt} } } \right]}

The first and second-order condition are given in Appendix A4 and evaluating the SOC at the optimum (m*) shows us that it is a local maximum as long as the benefits from migrating legally are high enough relative to the cost of waiting. However, if expected returns from migrating illegally are higher, migrants would switch until the indifference condition is met for the incoming entrant to the system: E(Ul)|m=m*=E(Ui)(1ν)m*1[νm*Rlα(eαm*WleαT)Cα(1eαm*Wl)]=Riα(eαWieαT)Cα(1eαWi) \matrix{ {E\left( {{U_l}} \right)\left| {_{m = {m^*}} = E\left( {{U_i}} \right)} \right.} \hfill \cr { \Rightarrow {{\left( {1 - \nu } \right)}^{{m^*} - 1}}\left[ {{{\nu {m^*}{R_l}} \over \alpha }\left( {{e^{ - \alpha {m^*}\left\langle {{W_l}} \right\rangle }} - {e^{ - \alpha T}}} \right) - {C \over \alpha }\left( {1 - {e^{ - \alpha {m^*}\left\langle {{W_l}} \right\rangle }}} \right)} \right] = {{{R_i}} \over \alpha }\left( {{e^{ - \alpha \left\langle {{W_i}} \right\rangle }} - {e^{ - \alpha T}}} \right) - {C \over \alpha }\left( {1 - {e^{ - \alpha \left\langle {{W_i}} \right\rangle }}} \right)} \hfill \cr } where 〈Wl〉 and 〈Wi〉 are the expected waiting times in the legal and illegal QS, respectively, and are both functions of the average rate of arrivals to the illegal queue (λi). Using a queuing theory result, 〈Wi〉 can be calculated in the same manner as before using a similar stability condition specified in Assumption 1.

Some standard results from queuing theory are given in Appendix A1. For a more detailed discussion refer to Medhi (2002).

Wi=1μiλi \left\langle {{W_i}} \right\rangle = {1 \over {{\mu _i} - {\lambda _i}}}

Next, I use Eq. (6) to examine the comparative statics of how changes in the parameters of the legal queue affect the rate of arrivals (λi) to the illegal queue and summarize them in the form of some results (proofs are in Appendix A5):

Comparative Statics Result 1

Ceteris paribus, increased traffic (ρ) in the legal QS increases the average rate of arrivals (λi) into the illegal QS.

The proof is intuitive; an increase in traffic (ρ=λoμl) \left( {\rho = {{{\lambda _o}} \over {{\mu _l}}}} \right) arises either from more people willing to migrate from the origin country or slower rates of processing migrants legally, both of which increase the expected legal waiting time. Longer waiting periods associated with legal travel are accompanied by higher costs reducing the expected returns from legal migration E(Ul*) E\left( {U_l^*} \right) . To maintain the condition of indifference (Eq. (6)), more migrants would switch over to the illegal channel, increasing the waiting time in the illegal queue.

Comparative Statics Result 2

Ceteris paribus, higher rates of acceptance (ν) in the legal QS lower the average rate of arrivals (λi) into the illegal QS.

This follows from an increase in the expected benefits from legal migration E(Ul*) E\left( {U_l^*} \right) as the chances of getting accepted for travel (ν) increase and the inverse relation between E(Ul*) E\left( {U_l^*} \right) and λi is proved in Result 1. This result is relevant for the role of immigration policy in preventing dangerous and illegal journeys undertaken often with smugglers in periods of mass migration.

The detailed proof in Appendix A5 shows that Result 2 holds as long as the returns from legal entry relative to the cost of waiting is high enough and Figure 2 illustrates this graphically using specific parameter values.

All figures illustrating the comparative statics findings use parameter values comparable to Djajić (2014).

Figure 2

Expected utility from legal immigration at different acceptance rates. Parameter values: Rl = 1000, C =10, α = 0.05, 〈Wl〉 = 4, T = 30.

Comparative Statics Result 3

Ceteris paribus, higher impatience in the form of higher discount rates (α) of the migrants leads to higher average rates of arrival (λi) into the illegal QS.

The intuition behind this proof is that as migrants become more impatient, they are more likely to switch over to the illegal queue. The higher gains from migrating legally would be worth less as they discount the future more. The formal proof given in Appendix A5 rests on precisely this condition that the absolute loss in expected utility from legal immigration E(Ul*) E\left( {U_l^*} \right) due to higher impatience is larger than that for the corresponding loss of expected utility from illegal immigration: E(Ul*)α<E(Ui)α {{\partial E\left( {U_l^*} \right)} \over {\partial \alpha }} < {{\partial E\left( {{U_i}} \right)} \over {\partial \alpha }}

Figure 3 illustrates that the optimal number of attempts (m*) increases as agents are more patient, i.e., have lower discount rates.

Figure 3

Expected utility from legal immigration at different discount rates. Parameter values: Rl = 1000, C =10, ν = 0.3, 〈Wl〉 = 4, T = 30.

Case II

Cases II and III illustrate similar findings as Case I but by using different aspects of QS. The previous case considered immigration policy to be comprised of an arbitrary acceptance rate, which is not always realistic. This case expresses the stringency of legal immigration in terms of a minimum waiting time (Wlc) \left( {W_l^c} \right) and thereby a minimum cost that the migrant should incur. I assume that this is specified exogenously by the destination country. The waiting time criteria may be thought of as the due diligence towards acquiring the requisite documents, skills, networks, money, etc., necessary for the journey. Alternatively, in case the migrant is in a UNHCR resettlement program, it can be time spent literally waiting in a refugee camp. The limiting criteria, Wlc=0 W_l^c = 0 and Wlc= W_l^c = \infty , lend themselves to immediate analysis. However, a finite Wlc W_l^c is not analytically feasible and I use simulations instead.

The expected return from legal migration after m attempts is: E(Ul)=mRl|(WlWlc)mWlTeαtdtC0mWleαtdt E\left( {{U_l}} \right) = m{R_l}|\left( {\left\langle {{W_l}} \right\rangle \ge W_l^c} \right)\int\limits_{m\left\langle {{W_l}} \right\rangle }^T {{e^{ - \alpha t}}dt - C\int\limits_0^{m\left\langle {{W_l}} \right\rangle } {{e^{ - \alpha t}}dt} } where | is the indicator function equal to 1 if the migrant has “waited” more than the critical amount specified by the destination country and 0 otherwise. The corresponding expected returns from illegal migration, where there is no minimum criteria, is: E(Ui)=RiWiTeαtdtC0Wieαtdt E\left( {{U_i}} \right) = {R_i}\int\limits_{\left\langle {{W_i}} \right\rangle }^T {{e^{ - \alpha t}}dt - C\int\limits_0^{\left\langle {{W_i}} \right\rangle } {{e^{ - \alpha t}}dt} } where mRl, Ri and C are the homogeneous benefits and waiting cost per unit of time as described earlier, applicable to all migrants.

The limiting cases are of no legal criteria: Wlc=0 W_l^c = 0 , and infinite legal criteria: Wlc= W_l^c = \infty . When there are no waiting criteria, success in the legal queue is certain and migrants do not have to make multiple attempts (m = 1). This case is analogous to countries which have open borders with each other (e.g., Schengen member countries). All migrants thus reach their destination legally and an illegal QS does not exist. Expected utility in this case is simply: E(Ul)=RlWlTeαtdtC0Wleαtdt E\left( {{U_l}} \right) = {R_l}\int\limits_{\left\langle {{W_l}} \right\rangle }^T {{e^{ - \alpha t}}dt - C\int\limits_0^{\left\langle {{W_l}} \right\rangle } {{e^{ - \alpha t}}dt} } where Wl=1μlλo \left\langle {{W_l}} \right\rangle = {1 \over {{\mu _l} - {\lambda _o}}} . On the other hand, an infinite waiting period criterion makes it impossible for migrants to legally reach their destination country. A real world example of this is can be cases of “extreme vetting” of citizens from certain countries or immigration from Israel to certain Arab states. In this case all migration is cannibalized by illegal routes and there will be no legal immigration. Returns to illegal migration are as specified in Eq. (10) with the expected waiting time equal to that of a standard M/M/1 queue: Wi=1μlλo \left\langle {{W_i}} \right\rangle = {1 \over {{\mu _l} - {\lambda _o}}}

Finite legal criteria: Wlc=Wlc* \boldsymbol{W}_\boldsymbol{l}^\boldsymbol{c}\boldsymbol{ = W}_\boldsymbol{l}^{\boldsymbol{c*}}

This intermediate case of a finite waiting time criterion is perhaps most realistic and general. It places some “reasonable” bounds on the level of diligence required from the migrant. This diligence may be in the form of actual waiting time or even the time spent in acquiring specific skills which form the basis of immigration – such as for science, technology, engineering, and mathematics (STEM) field workers in the US.

https://www.nber.org/digest/nov16/immigrants-play-key-role-stem-fields (Accessed: March 25, 2021)

It is standard for many European countries to explicitly require immigrants to reside within the country and wait a stipulated number of years before getting permanent residency or becoming naturalized or citizens, for example Permit C holders in Switzerland. However, such waiting requirements for accepted asylum status are more nuanced or implicit. The Pew Research Center estimates that the average waiting times for Syrian refugees ranges from 3 months in Germany to more than 1 year in Norway (Connor, 2017). These wait times are not explicit requirements, but depend on processing capacity, origin country, and political pressure on authorities to either accelerate or slow the processing of asylum applications.

If a request for refugee status is rejected, there is an appeal process in the EU which would involve another round of waiting.

Similarly, in the US, prospective immigrants are faced with different waiting time criteria due to country limits, which cap the number of green cards for any nationality. Under this requirement, immigrants who are applying from China, India, Mexico, and the Philippines, which are at or nearing the country limits, face waiting periods equal to several times that for other nationalities, between 7 years and 23 years (Obinna, 2020).

To model immigration choices under the regime of waiting time criteria, I define a common threshold patience parameter that all migrants are endowed with P = f (α) such that f (α) is a monotonically decreasing function of the discount rate defined in Case 1. This patience parameter represents the maximum number of times a migrant is willing to re-attempt legal migration before switching to illegal routes.

This is similar to m* described in Case I but it will not have the same functional form.

In this case, it is analytically infeasible to calculate the moments of the queue content and waiting time in the parallel systems. However, a simulation illustrates how queue content varies with Wlc* W_l^{c*} and P.

The simulations (Figures 4 and 5) show that:

The relative magnitude of illegal migration increases as the minimum waiting criteria, Wlc* W_l^{c*} is increased (from 18 to 40) or the patience parameter, P is decreased (from 4 to 1). The converse is true for the relative share of legal migration.

The queue content exhibits cycles, accumulating and reaching a peak before periodically emptying out once enough potential migrants achieve the minimum waiting criteria.

Figure 6 illustrates that cycles of immigration flows exhibit such cycles over time. However, this must be interpreted with caution because cyclic behavior in the queue content induced by the waiting time criteria is not possible to distinguish in the data from changes in immigration policy, seasonality and changes in origin-country circumstances.

This behavior is similar to that of a syphon studied in detail by Filliger and Hongler (2005).

Figure 4

Vertical axis shows steady state relative shares of legal and illegal migration flows and horizontal axis shows time for different patience parameters and critical waiting times.

Source: Simulations using Anylogic Parameter values: λo= 1, μl= 1.4, μi= 1.9 and a) Wlc*= 18, P= 4 (top panel) b) Wlc*= 40, P= 1 (bottom panel).

Figure 5

Steady state legal queue content and horizontal axis shows time.

Source: Simulations using Anylogic Parameter values: λo= 1, μj= 1.4, μi= 1.9, Wlc*= 18, P= 4.

Case III

This case models the stringency of legal channels of immigration in the form of limited waiting area capacity (Figure 6). It is similar to quotas – e.g., those imposed yearly on residence permits and short term permits in Switzerland.

https://www.ge.ch/moe/uk/autorisation.asp (Accessed: September 12, 2018)

This is an application of a textbook queuing regime and has been studied in depth by Naor (1969) in the context of imposing tolls to optimize social welfare. The derivations of the QS averages follow similarly with a capacity constraint K (refer to Appendix A3, Case III).

Figure 6

Countries with the highest illegal border crossings over the 5-year period 2010–2014 according to Frontex data.

The analysis is simplified in this case since migrants do not really have a choice about which route to take.

Another matter of interest may be to find the optimal K for the destination country by considering the cost of border control. Since optimal immigration policy itself is not the subject of this paper, I do not attempt it here.

Both queues operate in parallel with expected returns from legal and illegal migration given below: E(Ul)=RlWlTeαtdtC0mWleαtdt E\left( {{U_l}} \right) = {R_l}\int\limits_{\left\langle {{W_l}} \right\rangle }^T {{e^{ - \alpha t}}dt - C\int\limits_0^{m\left\langle {{W_l}} \right\rangle } {{e^{ - \alpha t}}dt} } and E(Ui)=RiWiTeαtdtC0Wieαtdt E\left( {{U_i}} \right) = {R_i}\int\limits_{\left\langle {{W_i}} \right\rangle }^T {{e^{ - \alpha t}}dt - C\int\limits_0^{\left\langle {{W_i}} \right\rangle } {{e^{ - \alpha t}}dt} }

As expected, an increase in the waiting area capacity (K) decreases the rate of arrivals (λi) into the illegal QS. Refer to Appendix A3, Eq. (19).

Before moving on to the empirical section, I summarize the implications of the theory below:

Given an increase in the number of people attempting to migrate from an origin country and fixed parameters of the legal QS, there will be a spillover into illegal immigration.

Greater stringency in the measures controlling legal immigration, holding the flow of overall potential migrants fixed, would lead to an increase in illegal immigration.

Higher levels of impatience among potential migrants would lead to more “switching- over” to the illegal channel.

Empirical Model

Due to the lack of and limitations in existing data, a structural estimation of the model is not feasible. However, I attempt a reduced form analysis to check whether the data contradict the theory of inter-dependent queues of legal and illegal immigration. One major limitation of my data is that it only includes individuals who have successfully reached their destination, legally or illegally. I have no information about the actual number of attempts at migration. Secondly, while the theoretical model consists of agents who are homogeneous in their observable characteristics, no such restriction can be applied to the data.

I use lagged and current values of immigrant flows as indicators of rates of arrival and successful queue completion described in the theoretical section, respectively. Origin-country violent conflict plays a dual role in that it acts as a push for more people to try to migrate and also makes people more impatient to leave (i.e., increases the discount factor α). Regarding impatience, I rely on existing results of Voors et al. (2012), which show that incidences of conflict have the effect of altering individuals’ time preferences, making them more impatient. The dataset refers to immigration into the Schengen region, which is comprised of many different countries; so, destination-country immigration policy is hard to capture. Year fixed effects are included to control for changes that occur at the Schengen region level.

Thus, the two main effects I look for in the data are of origin-country shocks of conflict and inter-QS effects. The equations to be estimated are: kit=αi1+λt1+β1cit1+π1kit1+γ1lit1+δ1xit+εit {k_{it}} = {\alpha _{i1}} + {\lambda _{t1}} + {\beta _1}{c_{it - 1}} + {\pi _1}{k_{it - 1}} + {\gamma _1}{l_{it - 1}} + {\delta _1}{x_{it}} + {\varepsilon _{it}} lit=αi2+λt2+β2cit1+π2lit1+γ2lit1+δ2xit+ηit {l_{it}} = {\alpha _{i2}} + {\lambda _{t2}} + {\beta _2}{c_{it - 1}} + {\pi _2}{l_{it - 1}} + {\gamma _2}{l_{it - 1}} + {\delta _2}{x_{it}} + {\eta _{it}} where the dependent variable kit and its lag refer to the log of IBCs into the Schengen region from country i in year t, and lit the corresponding log of inflow of documented or legal migrants.

According to Massey et al. (1993), over time, migration becomes independent of the individual causes that started the process and becomes its own cause. Decreasing costs and risks, network effects and institutional factors (for example humanitarian and illegal agencies) perpetuate the flow of immigrants once started. Persistence in the dependent variables would demonstrate this.

The variable cit−1 refers to the log of conflict-related deaths occurring 1 year prior to the year of migration. The lag is used to account for the fact that migration requires preparation or waiting time before the journey can be undertaken. Relevant covariates (xit) and year (λt) and country (αi) specific fixed effects are included. ɛit and ηit are the pure error terms.

Data sources

Available data on the EU refer to migrants who have successfully, either legally or illegally, entered the EU. The data on the inflow of migrants with legal status are from Eurostat, the statistical office of the EU. These data are disaggregated by country of citizenship and are available yearly. The definition of a “legal migrant” varies from country to country.

Eurostat defines immigration as the action by which a person establishes his or her usual residence in the territory of a Member State for a period that is, or is expected to be, of at least 12 months, having previously been usually resident in another Member State or a third country. Illegal migration or asylum seekers without legal status are not included in this Eurostat immigration dataset.

Schengen countries usually require an actual or intended stay of 12 months and report the data to Eurostat from population registers, administrative records, and national surveys.

Frontex records the number of detected IBCs via land and sea routes into the Schengen region. Disaggregated data by nationality are available from the 3rd quarter of 2007 and are updated monthly.

While there is bound to be some measurement error in the Frontex data as many entries into the Schengen region go undetected, the error is unlikely to be specific to any origin countries.

Figure 7 shows the evolution of IBCs from the six countries with the highest flows over 2010–2014 period. Pursuant to eyeballing the panels for Tunisia and Syria, we are presented with a sharp peak for the months immediately following their respective domestic conflicts.

Figure 7

Migration Queue (Case III).

Source: Author's representation.

For data on conflict, I use the Georeferenced Event Dataset (GED) from the Uppsala Conflict Data Program (UCDP version 17.1 2017). An event is an incident where armed force was used by an organized actor against another organized actor, or against civilians, resulting in at least one direct death at a specific location and a specific date. The UCDP dataset records three values for the number of conflict-related deaths: a low, high, and a best estimate. All estimates are sourced from publicly available and reliable information and are collected at the level of town and village for urban and rural areas respectively. For this paper, I collapse the data to the country level. The UCDP GED dataset does not yet include deaths from Syria as data collection is not complete at the granular level of towns and villages. I include Syria by using the conflict level data from the UCDP Battle-related Deaths (BRD) dataset.

The UCDP BRD dataset is an automatic filtering and aggregation of the UCDP GED and records deaths resulting from an armed conflict at multiple battle locations. I use only the BRDs which occurred solely within Syria. UCDP defines an armed conflict as a contested incompatibility that concerns government and/or territory over which the use of armed force between two parties, of which at least one is the government of a state, has resulted in at least 25 BRDs in 1 calendar year.

My sources for other relevant covariates are the World Development Indicators (WDI) for population density and World Governance Indicators (WGI) for institutional quality.

I use an estimate of rule of law from WGI which defines it as capturing perceptions of the extent to which agents have confidence in and abide by the rules of society, and in particular the quality of contract enforcement, property rights, the police, and the courts, as well as the likelihood of crime and violence. The estimate is a normalized indicator ranging from −2.5 to 2.5.

Complete data from all sources is available from 2008 to 2015; so, I restrict attention to this time period. Thus, I have a strongly balanced panel dataset with 8 years and 137 origin countries for IBCs and 218 origin countries for legal inflows. I transform all the above variables using the inverse hyperbolic sine transformation, except the institutions score to address the presence of a long right tail and zeros in the data.

The inverse hyperbolic sine transformation transforms variable yi to ln(yi + (yi2 + 1)1/2). It is defined at yi = 0, unlike the log transformation.

Summary statistics of the relevant variables are presented in Table 1.

Summary statistics

Variable name Category Mean Standard deviation N AR(1) Coefficient σα2σε2 {{{\boldsymbol{\sigma }_\boldsymbol{\alpha }^\boldsymbol{2}} \over {\boldsymbol{\sigma }_\boldsymbol{\varepsilon }^\boldsymbol{2}}}}
Log legal inflow Overall 5.808 2.888 1,744 0.177 0.97
Between 2.854 218
Within 0.478 8
Log illegal inflow Overall 3.479 3.257 1,096 0.296 0.81
Between 3.092 137
Within 1.052 8
Log CD Overall 1.115 2.466 1,768 0.309 0.68
Between 2.241 221
Within 1.039 8
Log CD difference Overall 0.800 2.025 1,768 0.230 0.71
Between 1.800 221
Within 0.934 8
Log GNI per capita Overall 9.871 1.246 1,274 0.781 0.96
Between 1.211 188
Within 0.077 6.8
Log population density Overall 5.097 1.567 1,644 0.965 0.98
Between 1.568 206
Within 0.046 8
Institutions score Overall −0.033 0.995 1,592 0.636 0.91
Between 0.990 200
Within 0.138 8

Note: AR(1) coefficients and the relative variance explained by fixed effects (σα2σε2) \left( {{{\sigma _\alpha ^2} \over {\sigma _\varepsilon ^2}}} \right) are calulated by estimating yit = ρyit−1 + αi + ɛit.

CD, conflict deaths.

Identification strategy

The parameters of interest are the βs and γs of Eqs (15) and (16). Due to potential endogeneity and the dynamic panel setting, I use a GMM approach to estimate the coefficients of interest using internal as well as external instruments. The external instrument to consistently estimate the effect of conflict arises from the dataset itself. The UCDP dataset records three values for the number of battle related deaths: a low, high, and a best estimate. The estimates are collected from third parties such as news agencies, international and non-governmental organizations. In addition, the sources also include reports from the warring parties themselves (governments and opposing groups). Due to the difficulties in accessing accurate information during a violent conflict and the vested interests of governments or opposition parties in releasing accurate fatalities, there are discrepancies regarding the exact number of conflict-related deaths. This is even greater when conflicts are spread out geographically over a region, some locations of which are inaccessible. The discrepancies, measured by the difference between the high and the low estimate, are positively and strongly correlated with the level of the best estimate, thereby satisfying the criterion of instrument relevance. This should be unsurprising as it is harder for independent reporters or watchdogs to access locations during conflicts occurring at a massive scale (Themnér and Wallensteen, 2014).

Refer to Iraq Body Count studies: https://www.iraqbodycount.org/

The second criterion of the exclusion restriction is more complicated to support. The difference in the high and low estimates of death may actually be picking up the nature of institutions instead of the intensity of the conflict itself. To account for this, I control for the quality of institutions in the country by using the rule of law indicator. Further, if we consider the group of countries which have no discrepancies in the measurement of deaths in the presence of violent conflict, their mean score on the institutions indicator is negative (−0.61), which is clearly a counter to the argument that the instrument is picking up institutional quality.

In this dynamic panel setting of lagged effects and in the absence of sufficient external instruments, I use a GMM approach to exploit all available moment conditions using internal instruments. Due to the possibility of persistence and the high relative share of variance in fixed effects (σα2σε2) \left( {{{\sigma _\alpha ^2} \over {\sigma _\varepsilon ^2}}} \right) , the first-differenced GMM estimates may suffer from poor finite sample properties, namely bias and imprecision, since lagged levels are weak instruments for first-differences (Blundell and Bond, 2000). Hence, I estimate the model using system GMM, which estimates the model using the equations in levels and differences to improve the strength of internal instruments. Lastly, another issue potentially compounding the endogeneity problem is the possibility of serially correlated errors. This is addressed by the common factor representation below given by Blundell and Bond, 2000 and also implemented by Arcand et al. (2008). εit=θ1εit1+eitlit=αi1(1θ1)αi1*+(λt1θ1λt11)λt1*+π1cit1+π2cit2+θ1lit1+π3xit+π4xit1+eit \matrix{ {{\varepsilon _{it}}} \hfill & = \hfill & {{\theta _1}{\varepsilon _{it - 1}} + {e_{it}}} \hfill \cr {{l_{it}}} \hfill & = \hfill & {\underbrace {{\alpha _{i1}}\left( {1 - {\theta _1}} \right)}_{\alpha _{i1}^*} + \underbrace {\left( {{\lambda _{t1}} - {\theta _1}{\lambda _t}1 - 1} \right)}_{\lambda _{t1}^*} + {\pi _1}{c_{it - 1}} + {\pi _2}{c_{it - 2}} + {\theta _1}{l_{it - 1}} + {\pi _3}{x_{it}} + {\pi _4}{x_{it - 1}} + {e_{it}}} \hfill \cr } ηit=θ2ηit1+νitkit=αi2(1θ2)αi2*+(λt2θ2λt21)λt2*+π^1cit1+π^2cit2+θ2kit1+π^3xit+π^4xit1+νit \matrix{ {{\eta _{it}}} \hfill & = \hfill & {{\theta _2}{\eta _{it - 1}} + {\nu _{it}}} \hfill \cr {{k_{it}}} \hfill & = \hfill & {\underbrace {{\alpha _{i2}}\left( {1 - {\theta _2}} \right)}_{\alpha _{i2}^*} + \underbrace {\left( {{\lambda _{t2}} - {\theta _2}{\lambda _t}2 - 1} \right)}_{\lambda _{t2}^*} + {{\hat \pi }_1}{c_{it - 1}} + {{\hat \pi }_2}{c_{it - 2}} + {\theta _2}{k_{it - 1}} + {{\hat \pi }_3}{x_{it}} + {{\hat \pi }_4}{x_{it - 1}} + {\nu _{it}}} \hfill \cr }

Results using the above estimation techniques are presented in the next section.

Results

I focus first only on the effect of conflict and omit the lagged legal and illegal inflows from the right-hand side of the model. Results using pooled Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) and within-estimators are given in Tables 2 and 3. The significance of the positive conflict coefficient remains for IBCs after introducing controls and fixed effects but not for legal inflows. In Column 4 of Tables 2 and 3, I restrict the sample to only those countries with any present or past incidences of conflict within the panel length, to explore further the relationship between the two migration variables and conflict. The significance of the positive conflict coefficient remains for IBCs but not for legal inflows. This illustrates that the relationship between conflict and illegal migrant flows is not driven solely by the differences between countries that experience violent conflict and those that do not.

Pooled OLS and within-estimator dependent variable: Illegal inflow

OLS Within Within Within

All All All Restricted sample

(1) (2) (3) (4)
Log CDt−1 0.306*** (0.035) 0.094** (0.040) 0.082** (0.038) 0.071* (0.036)
Log population density 0.244*** (0.050) 6.761*** (2.571) 4.234 (3.394)
Institutions −1.390*** (0.095) −0.813 (0.579) −1.419** (0.672)
Constant 0.887*** (0.336) 2.987*** (0.130) −29.881** (12.270) −17.052 (15.764)
Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country fixed effects Yes Yes Yes
Adjusted R2 0.273 0.130 0.171 0.246
Number of observations 920 959 920 497
Number of countries 137 132 71

Note:

p < 0.10,

p < 0.05,

p < 0.01.

Standard errors, given below coefficients in parentheses, are clustered at the country level.

CD, conflict deaths.

Pooled OLS and within-estimator dependent variable: Legal inflow

OLS Within Within Within

All All All Restricted sample

(1) (2) (3) (4)
Log CDtl 0.302*** (0.016) 0.033 (0.034) −0.000 (0.011) −0.009 (0.012)
Log population density −0.231*** (0.056) 0.648 (0.562) 0.599 (0.685)
Institutions 0.268*** (0.071) 0.000 (0.196) −0.450** (0.176)
Constant 6.905*** (0.321) 5.556*** (0.062) 2.943 (2.796) 4.008 (3.306)
Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country fixed effects Yes Yes Yes
Adjusted R2 0.101 0.039 0.054 0.142
Number of observations 1,364 1,526 1,364 532
Number of countries 218 196 76

Note:

p < 0.10,

p < 0.05,

p < 0.01.

Standard errors, given below coefficients in parentheses, are clustered at the country level.

CD, conflict deaths.

Now, given that there are endogeneity issues, most obviously due to omission of lagged inter-queue variables, the coefficients in Tables 2 and 3 are likely to be inconsistent. As mentioned in section 4.2, I use the difference between the high and low estimates of conflict deaths (CD) as an Instrumental Variables (IV) for its best estimate. This is driven by strong correlation between the level of discrepancy and the level of the conflict itself. Controlling for the quality of institutions, as measured by the rule of law indicator, this discrepancy should not be related to immigration in any other way.

Using the difference between high and low estimates of CD as an IV, Table 4 shows that lagged conflict in origin countries positively affects IBCs but has no effect on the legal inflow of migrants into Schengen countries. The coefficient for conflict is relatively stable across specifications. There is a strong mechanical correlation between the IV and the endogenous conflict variable (refer to Table 4, Part B). This “relevance” of the difference in high and low estimates of CD to its best estimate is because for observations which have no conflict, the difference in estimates is also equal to zero. Thus, I restrict the sample to only those countries which see any present or past incidences of conflict within the panel length (Columns 3 and 6, Table 4) and find that the result still holds. The strength of the instrument does not rely on mechanical relevance alone (Columns 3 and 6, Table 4 Part B).

Two-Stage Least Squares (2SLS) estimator

Part A Legal inflow Illegal Inflow



All All Restricted sample All All Restricted sample

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Log CDt−1 0.042* (0.022) −0.000 (0.013) −0.010 (0.013) 0.120*** (0.039) 0.120*** (0.041) 0.106** (0.041)
Log population density 0.648 (0.410) 0.600 (0.499) 6.783*** (1.610) 4.162** (2.111)
Institutions −0.000 (0.154) −0.453*** (0.130) −0.724* (0.371) −1.288*** (0.458)
Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Part B First stage dependent variable: Log CD

Log CD difference 0.828*** (0.041) 0.800*** (0.044) 0.782*** (0.045) 0.824*** (0.040) 0.789*** (0.043) 0.779*** (0.043)
Log population density 0.628 (0.796) 3.522* (1.944) 1.133 (1.130) 3.289* (1.995)
Institutions −0.576*** (0.178) −1.831*** (0.454) −1.096*** (0.316) −1.811*** (0.462)
Number of observations 1,526 1,364 532 959 920 497
Number of Countries 218 196 76 137 132 71
Kleibergen-Paap F-stat 405.913 327.501 302.436 430.805 340.704 322.067

Note:

p < 0.10,

p < 0.05,

p < 0.01.

Standard errors, given below coefficients in parentheses, are clustered at the country level.

CD, conflict deaths.

Finally, I turn to the complete model (Eqs (15) and (16)), which includes the inter-queue effects.

I use the Stata program by Roodman (2009) for all dynamic panel estimations.

Table 5 uses lags t − 1 to t − 3 of endogenous variables as instruments and the external instrument mentioned earlier. All estimates are calculated using the two-step covariance matrices along with the finite-sample correction given by Windmeijer (2005), which makes two-step robust estimations more efficient in small T large N datasets. However, the results presented in Columns 5 and 6 of Table 5 use the one-step covariance matrix and the findings are not robust to the two-step covariance matrix estimation.

GMM estimates

Difference GMM System GMM Common factor



Illegal Legal Illegal Legal Illegal Legal

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Log illegal inflowt−1 0.103 (0.085) −0.030 (0.030) 0.752*** (0.047) 0.018 (0.012) 0.806*** (0.047) −0.008 (0.016)
Log illegal inflowt−2 0.027 (0.016)
Log legal inflowt−1 −0.105 (0.152) −0.140* (0.074) 0.266*** (0.085) 0.899*** (0.031) 0.050 (0.088) 0.903*** (0.027)
Log legal inflowt−2 0.163** (0.081)
Log CDt−1 0.010 (0.059) −0.009 (0.020) 0.071** (0.034) 0.013 (0.011) 0.063** (0.032) 0.002 (0.013)
Log CDt−2 0.015 (0.031) 0.008 (0.015)
Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes
Number of observations 804 804 938 938 804 804
Number of countries 134 134 134 134 134 134
Number of instruments 46 46 71 71 73 73
AR(1) p-stat 0.0004 0.1682 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
AR(2) p-stat 0.1811 0.7931 0.3345 0.0821 0.4006 0.1477
Hansen p-statistic 0.0004 0.0574 0.0194 0.0645 0.0085 0.0601

Note:

p < 0.10,

p < 0.05,

p < 0.01.

Standard errors, given below the coefficient in parentheses, are clustered by country. Columns 1–4 use the two-step and Columns 5 and 6 use the one-step co-variance matrix estimations.

CD, conflict deaths; GMM, generalized method of moments.

From Table 5, there is evidence of positive spillovers from legal immigration flows on illegal flows but none in the opposite direction. There is also evidence of persistence of own queue effects. The previous results regarding the effect of conflict related deaths still hold, in that they positively affect illegal immigration flows and have no effect on legal flows.

Additional results

One drawback of the above results is that it does not account for the inherent differences between people attempting to migrate legally compared to those who do so illegally. Documented migration to Europe usually occurs under the following categories – remunerated activities, family reunification, education and humanitarian reasons. Differences within individuals from the same country would make some people more eligible to meet these criteria than others. Since I do not have data on individual level characteristics, I cannot control for them. However, the theory in Section 3 implies that given the same characteristics of individuals, migrating via the legal queue is likely to involve larger waiting costs that lead some people to switch over to the illegal channel. Looking at the effect of violent conflict on the flows of legally resettled people who might share similar characteristics within the origin countries gives evidence to these waiting costs.

“Resettlement is one tool to help displaced persons in need of protection reach Europe safely and legally, and receive protection for as long as necessary. It is a durable solution which includes selection and transfer of refugees from a country where they seek protection to another country” EPRS, 2017. The UNHCR has to determine whether an applicant is a refugee according to the 1951 Geneva Convention, and has to identify resettlement as the most appropriate solution. From Table 6 we see that the relationship between violent conflict and the magnitude of resettled persons is not very robust within the dataset available. Only the third lag of CD is significant using the within estimator and this significance becomes weaker after introducing other covariates. The same goes for results from 2SLS estimation using the difference in estimates of CD as an IV for CD.

Within and 2SLS estimators dependent variable: Log of resettled persons

Within Within Within Within 2SLS 2SLS

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Log CDt−1 0.072 (0.048)
Log CDt−2 0.072 (0.045)
Log CDt−3 0.130*** (0.048) 0.077* (0.046) 0.143** (0.066) 0.068 (0.066)
Log population density −1.059 (2.129) −1.085 (2.131)
Institutions −0.400 (0.328) −0.407 (0.332)
Constant 0.617*** (0.102) 0.674*** (0.087) 0.464*** (0.096) 5.755 (10.530) 0.445*** (0.118) 5.896 (10.538)
Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Country fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Adjusted R2 0.013 0.012 0.036 0.017
Number of observations 1,576 1,379 1,182 952 1,182 952
Number of groups 197 197 197 192 197 192

Note:

p < 0.10,

p < 0.05,

p < 0.01.

Standard errors, given below the coefficient in parentheses, are clustered by country.

CD, conflict deaths.

Discussion

This paper is addressed to two broad audiences. The first audience comprises of development economists who are working on immigration and would be interested in alternative frameworks to study mass migration and crises therein. The second audience includes those economists who work on stochastic processes and specifically, queuing theory, who would be interested in its application to real-world phenomenon such as migration. This paper provides a stylized model focusing on how migration crises emerge out of linkages between legal and illegal channels of entry and the dynamic nature of the same. However, it has several limitations. Firstly, it does not account for migrant heterogeneity and this is one research area with great potential for future work.

An emerging sub-field of queuing theory is real-time queuing (RTQ) theory which allows heterogeneity in the form of personalized deadlines to exit the queue. This allows for a dynamic evolution of migrant profiles and price of migration based on the urgency and ability to pay of migrants.

Secondly, the current framework is restrictive in that it does not allow for complete breakdowns of migration control services as we have witnessed in the recent past. Under such circumstances of discontinuity, massive flows would, in fact, drive costs of illegal migration further down. Despite these limitations, this baseline illustrates how the migration choices of others may influence individual decisions beyond a certain threshold level of traffic.

Empirically, this paper attempts to study the effect of conflict on different channels of immigration. To the my knowledge, this has not been addressed as yet in the context of the recent crisis and particularly, has not made use of the Frontex dataset on IBCs into the Schengen region. While I cannot estimate the full structural model and the panel length of the data is only 8 years, the results show clearly the one-way inter-queue effects spilling over from legal to illegal flows and the lack of sensitivity of legal immigration to origin-country shocks such as conflict. It is however quite possible that the short length of the panel does not allow these effects to show up – but that is precisely support for the frictions that the theory assumes.

Although much attention has been given to South–North migration in the media, North–North and South–South migration together account for a majority (59%) of global immigration with South–South migration having the largest share (UNDESA, 2013). Crisis-like scenarios regarding South–North migration emerge due to the rigidity and slow-moving nature of legal processes of resettlement and assessment of asylum applications. A role for future research would be to shed light on immigration policies that account for inter-linkages between different channels instead of addressing individual channels as systems in isolation.