Comparative Analysis of Hedonic Wage and Discrete Choice Models in Valuing Job Safety
Pubblicato online: 07 gen 2025
Pagine: 1 - 16
DOI: https://doi.org/10.2478/ceej-2025-0001
Parole chiave
© 2025 Nan Zhang, published by Sciendo
This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.
The hedonic wage model and discrete choice model are the two most widely used nonmarket valuation methods. The hedonic wage model is a revealed preference method which is widely used in estimating the job safety (referred as “value of a statistical life, VSL” in literature). When the job market is in equilibrium, the price of jobs (wages) is a non-linear function of job attributes and worker attributes. By regressing wages on a specific job/worker attribute, one can infer the marginal implicit price of this job/worker attribute, which also equals the marginal willingness to pay (MWTP) for the chosen quantity of that attribute.
Discrete choice models provide an alternative way of valuing nonmarket goods and can be applied to both revealed data and hypothetical data. The Random Utility Model (RUM) is the most widely adopted discrete choice model. The RUM model maximises the probability that a specified bundle of attributes is chosen by an individual to maximise the utility, which is defined over attributes (such as the housing attributes in residential sorting literature, or job attributes in survey-based choice experiment studies focusing on the job market). To the author’s knowledge, the discrete choice model has not been applied to real labour market data to study the willingness to pay for job attributes, such as job risk reduction.
This study applies the discrete choice model to real labour market data in Taiwan to estimate the MWTP for job safety and compares the results from the hedonic wage model using the same data. This study finds that the hedonic wage model outperforms the discrete choice model in valuing job safety, suggesting that the hedonic wage model provides a more reliable estimate of marginal willingness to pay (MWTP) for job risk reduction. This study also explores the possible explanations for the unsatisfying performance of the discrete choice model.
This study contributes to three branches of valuation literature: the choice experiment (CE) studies that focus on the labour market, the residential sorting literature, and the comparison between the hedonic price model and the discrete choice model.
First, this study applies the discrete choice model to real labour market data to examine workers’ industry choices. In choice experiment (CE) studies, subjects are presented with hypothetical industry options, each characterised by different levels of attributes, including wages and other non-monetary job features, and asked to select the industry that maximises their utility. By analysing workers’ choices, researchers can assess the relative importance of various attributes and infer their willingness to pay (WTP) for these non-monetary features. However, CE studies rely on stated preferences and suffer from hypothetical bias.
The second line of literature this study connects to is the residential sorting literature. These studies adopt discrete choice models to investigate consumers’ residential choices (according to the living cost, earning opportunity, moving cost, and environmental attributes of different residential locations) and to infer their WTP for environmental goods such as air quality and climate (Cragg and Kahn, 1997; Sinha and Cropper, 2013; Chay and Greenstone, 2005; Bayer et al., 2009; Freeman et al., 2019). Currently, this sorting literature has never been applied to the labour market to study WTP for job attributes, such as job risk.
The third line of literature that this study contributes to is the comparison between the performance of the hedonic and discrete choice models in the housing market. For now, there is no unanimous agreement on which model performs better. For instance, Cropper et al. (1993) compare the logit model and hedonic price model in estimating the preference for housing attributes in a single market through simulation. They find that the two approaches perform equally well in estimating the marginal value, but the logit model outperforms the hedonic price model in valuing non-marginal changes of attributes. Palmquist and Israngkura (1999) investigate the willingness to pay for air quality improvements with both the hedonic price model and the random utility model. They conclude that the hedonic wage model is more successful than the random utility model when multiple markets are available. Sinha et al. (2021) compare the two approaches in estimating MWTP for climate attributes with housing market data. They find that the discrete choice model results in an MWTP for warm winters twice as large as the hedonic price model, though the MWTP for cooler summers is about the same for both approaches.
The structure of this paper is arranged as follows: Section 2 compares the theoretical framework of the two valuation approaches. Section 3 describes the data used in this study. Section 4 estimates the MWTP for job safety with the three discrete choice specifications and the hedonic wage model. Section 5 discusses the differences between the two models and concludes.
The discrete choice model is widely used in valuing environmental goods and recreation demand. By exploring how individuals make choices among discrete alternatives, such as different brands of commodities, transportation modes, fishing sites, occupation/industries, etc., the discrete choice model can be used to infer consumers’ WTP for an attribute and to predict the changes in demand for a certain alternative associated with the changes in attributes. The random utility model (RUM) is the most widely adopted discrete choice model, which is based on the work of economists including Manski and McFadden (Manski and Lerman, 1977; McFadden, 1974; McFadden, 1980; McFadden & Train, 2000).
Suppose a worker
Following the random utility studies, this study also assumes a linear representative utility function. Worker
The fixed coefficient
The mixed logit model is a very flexible model that can solve the limitations of the standard logit model by allowing for unobserved random taste variation and unrestricted substitution pattern. In addition, the panel data mixed logit model can also address the correlation of the unobserved tastes over time. McFadden and Train (2000) show that the mixed logit model can be used to approximate any random utility model.
In the mixed logit model, the coefficient (
As shown in the first order condition (equation 3),
The hedonic wage model is built based on the hedonic price theory by Thaler and Rosen (1976). A job can be seen as a composite good with its attributes. From a worker’s perspective, a job can be considered as a differentiated good consisting of various job characteristics, such as flexibility in working hours, the number of paid vacation days, working conditions, prestige, training and enhancement of skills, the risk of accidental injury or exposure to toxic substances, etc. Different jobs have different bundles of characteristics and different wage rates. Wage differentials can be interpreted as the implicit prices of job characteristics. From the perspective of employers, they are the suppliers of the job attributes. At the same time, employers can be viewed as choosing from among a set of workers of different characteristics. Thus, the job market also functions as the implicit market of job attributes and worker attributes.
The hedonic wage equation is an equilibrium relationship that reflects the interaction of supply and demand for worker attributes. It is the double-envelope of both the firm’s iso-profit curves and workers’ indifferent curves. In the hedonic wage model, the wages in a job market reflect the equilibrium relationship between workers and firms. However, the discrete choice model considers the wage as a job attribute that is exogenous. The hedonic wage equation is a function of the worker attributes
After the estimation, the implicit price of risk (
The implicit price of risk (
Three levels of data are combined in this study. The first is the individual-level data from the PSFD (Panel Survey of Family Dynamics) conducted in Taiwan. The PSFD survey started in 1999 and collected information on workers’ personal information (wage, education, gender, work experience, etc.). The survey is of high quality and has a panel structure, conducted every year before 2012 and every two years after 2012.
The currently unemployed respondents are excluded in the study, following the literature. The agricultural sector is excluded because the wage equation in the agriculture industry is different from other industries. The mining sector and the public sector are also excluded because there are not enough observations in these two sectors. The lack of observations in a given industry will make it hard to get an accurately estimated wage equation for this industry, which is required for the discrete choice model. For the same reason, only data from the years 2016 and 2018 are used because other waves of survey do not have enough observations for each of the seven industries. Thus, we end up with seven industries: Manufacturing, Construction, Catering, Transportation, Finance, Science, and Service. The number of observations in the years 2016 and 2018 are 2293 and 1903, respectively.
Then comes the industry-level data, including job risk, working hours, and unemployment rates. The industry mortality risk (
There are two sources of variations in the job risk of an individual, one being the change in risk over time if the worker stays in the same industry, and the other comes from the worker switching to a different sector.
There are two considerations for choosing the industry-specific job attributes except job risk. Following the choice experiment (CE) studies on labour market choices, wage is considered one of the most important factors in workers’ labour market choices by most studies (Guo et al., 2010; Mangham and Hanson, 2008). Besides wages, working intensity is also an important factor in deciding which job to take (Kornstad and Thoresen, 2007). In this study, I use the average monthly total working hours (
The industry mortality risk, average working hours by industry, and unemployment rates by industry are all from the Bureau of Labour Insurance, Ministry of Labour, Taiwan (
This study also incorporates town-level climate data, recognising climate as an important factor in both residential location choices and its influence on labour supply and wage income in a given city. The analysis focuses on two key climate variables: the average temperatures in January and July (1981–2005), representing the coldest and warmest months in Taiwan. The climate data, provided by the Taiwan Climate Change Projection and Information Platform (TCCIP)(1), is of high quality. Our survey dataset covers 218 out of 352 townships in Taiwan, with the town-level climate data matched to individual worker data based on the workplace addresses reported in the survey.
The variable definition and the summary statistics of the variables used in this study are shown in Table 1.
Variable Descriptive Statistics
Individual (Obs. 4035) | wage | Yearly wage in 2014 value (unit: 1000 TWD) | 537. 2 | 28.5 | 5587.7 |
eduyear | Education years | 14.1 | 0.0 | 22.0 | |
feduyear | Father’s education years | 9.2 | 0.0 | 22.0 | |
female | 1 if female, 0 otherwise | 0.4 | 0.0 | 1.0 | |
age | age | 35.1 | 25.0 | 79.0 | |
marriage | 1 if married, 0 otherwise | 0.5 | 0.0 | 1.0 | |
scale | Number of employees in the firm | 212.2 | 2.0 | 500.0 | |
wexp | Working experience years | 13.6 | 1.0 | 71.0 | |
healthlevel | 1 for very good health, 5 for very bad health | 3.6 | 1.0 | 5.0 | |
Industry (seven industries) | risk | industry mortality rates, unit: 1/1,000,000 | 23.6 | 0.0 | 124.3 |
workhour_alt | industry average monthly total work hours, unit: hour | 169.8 | 159.8 | 176.0 | |
unem_alt | industry unemployment rates, unit: % | 3.2 | 2.6 | 4.6 | |
Town (218 towns) | TJAN | township-level average January temperature (Celsius) from 1981 to 2005 | 16.4 | 13.1 | 20.8 |
TJUL | township-level average July temperature (Celsius) from 1981 to 2005 | 28.8 | 26.4 | 30.3 | |
Regional dummy | NORTH | 1 if respondent lives in Northern Taiwan, 0 otherwise | 0.5 | 0.0 | 1.0 |
CENTER | 1 if respondent lives in central Taiwan, 0 otherwise | 0.2 | 0.0 | 1.0 | |
SOUTH | 1 if respondent lives in southern Taiwan, 0 otherwise | 0.2 | 0.0 | 1.0 | |
EAST | 1 if respondent lives in eastern Taiwan, 0 otherwise | 0.0 | 0.0 | 1.0 |
Source: PSFD 2016, 2018; Bureau of Labour Insurance, Ministry of Labour. Taiwan Climate Change Projection and Information Platform (TCCIP) project
We do not observe the wage a worker can earn in every industry but the wage in the industry he/she has already chosen. The first step, which is the same as in the sorting literature, is to predict wages in alternative industries that are not chosen by a worker.
For each of the seven industries, a wage equation was estimated in both years to capture the wage structure in this specific industry and then used to predict the wage income one specific worker would get if he/she chose this industry. The control variables mainly include factors that affect one’s productivity, such as gender, age, education, etc. The results of the first stage wage regressions for 2016 and 2018 are shown in Tables A1 and A2 in the Appendix. For later analysis in the discrete choice model, wage_alt will be the reported real wage for industries chosen by workers, and the wages in alternative industries that workers do not choose will be the predicted wages based on these industry wage regressions.
This study estimates three different discrete choice models: the conditional logit model, which assumes all coefficients are fixed (that workers have homogenous tastes over industry attributes); the mixed logit model, which assumes the coefficient of job attributes to be random, thus allowing for the heterogeneity in tastes variety; and the panel-data mixed logit model, which allows the coefficients to be correlated over time.
First, the random utility model in equation (4) was estimated using the conditional logit model with pooled observations from 2016 and 2018. The results are shown in Columns (1)-(2), Table 2.
Regression Results-Discrete Choice Model
wage_alt | 0.0017*** | 0.0013*** | 0.0022*** | 0.0018*** | 0.0018*** | 0.0016*** |
risk_alt | –0.1091*** | –0.0986*** | –0.1244*** | –0.1162*** | –0.1632*** | –0.1422*** |
workhour_alt | 0.0251** | 0.0096 | 0.1633*** | 0.1039*** | 0.1529*** | 0.1085*** |
unem_alt | −0.7097*** | −0.5777*** | 0.3434 | 0.1138 | −0.1729 | −0.2892 |
sd(risk_alt) | 0.3826*** | 0.3186*** | 0.2546*** | 0.2323*** | ||
sd(workhour_alt) | 0.4681*** | 0.4270*** | 0.4601*** | 0.4771*** | ||
sd(umem_alt) | 0.0026 | 0.0041 | 2.3677*** | 2.7743*** | ||
Construction | ||||||
eduyear | −0.2003*** | −1.0500** | −1.0161*** | |||
age | −0.0134 | 0.0941 | 0.1238** | |||
female | −1.0217*** | −15.3042*** | −11.4380*** | |||
_cons | 9.0968*** | 11.2592*** | −42.8469*** | −19.2340 | −19.0045*** | −5.0814 |
Catering | ||||||
eduyear | −0.1084*** | −0.1538* | −0.1549** | |||
age | −0.0296*** | −0.0946*** | −0.0997*** | |||
female | 0.6325*** | 3.2816*** | 3.2010*** | |||
_cons | −2.0309*** | 0.7968 | −1.3451*** | 2.2099 | −1.3025*** | 2.5388* |
Transportation | ||||||
eduyear | −0.0522 | −0.1804 | −0.1984*** | |||
age | −0.0162 | −0.0123 | 0.0004 | |||
female | −0.3839* | −3.2871*** | −2.4575*** | |||
_cons | −2.9876 | 1.8339** | −8.5789*** | −2.9876 | −5.4116*** | 0.1871 |
Finance | ||||||
eduyear | 0.2072*** | 0.2016** | 0.2588*** | |||
age | 0.0058 | −0.0370 | −0.0454** | |||
female | 0.6392*** | 3.1610*** | 2.9912*** | |||
_cons | −3.7770*** | −7.1861*** | −8.5789*** | −9.0142*** | −8.6711*** | |
Science | ||||||
eduyear | 0.0321 | 0.0385 | 0.0385 | |||
age | 0.0105 | −0.0011 | 0.0315 | |||
female | 0.4214*** | 0.6866*** | 1.1440*** | |||
_cons | −0.6070*** | −1.8486*** | −1.9667*** | −2.4552*** | −2.9669*** | −5.4924*** |
Service | ||||||
eduyear | 0.1624*** | 0.1287 | 0.2505*** | |||
age | −0.0345*** | −0.1047*** | −0.1237*** | |||
female | 1.1372*** | 3.9960*** | 4.1265*** | |||
_cons | −2.2029*** | −4.0223*** | −2.1834*** | −2.8356 | −2.4155*** | −4.1438** |
N | 32,347 | 32,347 | 32,347 | 32,347 | 32,347 | 32,347 |
Pseudo R2 | 1.41% | 1.32% | 30.93% | 31.52% | 27.36% | 28.19% |
Log-likelihood | −7388.89 | −7085.43 | −7127.41 | −6923.56 | −6107.19 | −5918.74 |
AIC | 14797.78 | 14226.87 | 14280.81 | 13909.11 | 12750.25 | 11899.47 |
Note:
As can be seen from Columns (1) and (2) in Table 2, workers prefer industries that have higher wage income, longer working hours, lower risks, and lower unemployment rates. The preferences are heterogeneous across workers. Compared with Manufacturing, high-education workers are less likely to choose Construction and Catering but are more likely to work in the Finance and Service industries. Older workers are less likely to choose a job in the Catering and Science industries. Female workers are less likely to get a job in the Construction and Transportation industries and are more likely to work in Catering, Finance, Science, and Service, as expected. Including the worker attributes can help solve the observed heterogeneity in preferences. However, there are cases in which unobserved worker attributes could also affect workers’ industry choices and can be addressed with the mixed logit model.
Because of the advantages of the mixed logit model in the flexible substitution pattern and allowing for unobserved heterogeneity, this study estimates a mixed logit model with pooled observations of 2016 and 2018. Following the literature, such as Huang et al. (2018), the coefficients of industry attributes are assumed to follow a random distribution, while the coefficient of income/cost (in our case, wage) is assumed to be fixed. In Model 6, personal attributes such as gender, education, and age are included to explore the observable heterogeneity in tastes. The results are shown in Models 3–4 in Table 2. In Model 3, only industry attributes are considered, and in Model 4, worker attributes are also included.
We can see that workers still prefer industries with higher wages, longer working hours, and lower mortality rates, similar to what we find in the conditional logit model. However, the coefficients of unemployment become insignificant, suggesting that unemployment has no impact on workers’ industry choices. In Model 4, the coefficient of
Similarly, the mean of the coefficient of workhour is 0.104, and the mean of the standard deviation of workhour is 0.427. Both are significant. The relatively large standard deviations suggest that workers have various tastes over working hours. However, the mean and the standard deviation of the coefficients of unemployment rates are insignificant. The individual-specific attributes affect the industry choices in a similar way as those found in the conditional logit model.
The panel-data mixed logit model has the advantage of capturing the correlation of workers’ choices over time and is very useful for modelling consumer behaviour such as habit formation and/or variation-seeking. In our context, it is reasonable to assume that workers prefer to choose the same industry as they did in the last period; otherwise, their work experience and skills accumulated in the last job will be less appreciated. In this specification, we continue our assumption that all workers have the same preference regarding wages but heterogeneous preferences for risks, workhours, and unemployment. The regression results are shown in Models 5 and 6, Table 2.
As we can see, workers show heterogeneous preferences for job attributes: they prefer jobs with higher wages, longer working hours, and lower job risks. The coefficients of workhour are positive, with substation variations among the population, suggesting that average workers are more likely to be engaged in industries that have longer working hours. The coefficients of unemployment rates are negative but not significant, suggesting that overall, unemployment rates do not affect how workers choose industries.
Compared with Manufacture, high-education workers prefer the Finance and Science industries over Construction, Catering, and Transportation. Older workers are more likely to be working in Construction and less likely to work in Catering, Finance, and Service. Female workers prefer Service, Catering, Finance, and Science and are least likely to be engaged in Construction. By comparing the regression results of the three specifications using the AIC and log-likelihood, we find that the panel mixed logit models perform better than the other models.
In the discrete choice models, the marginal willingness to pay (MWTP) for one unit of risk reduction (1/1000,000) can be calculated as follows:
First, a separate hedonic wage model (equation 14) was estimated using data from 2016 and 2018, respectively. Then, the hedonic wage model was re-estimated with pooled data from these two years. The hedonic wage model regression results are shown in Table 3.
The Hedonic Wage Model Results
risk_alt | 0.0006* (0.0003) | 0.0011*** (0.0004) | 0.0008*** (0.0002) | 0.0012*** (0.0003) | 0.0012*** (0.0003) |
eduyear | 0.0660*** (0.0052) | 0.0765*** (0.0054) | 0.0710*** (0.0038) | 0.0711*** (0.0038) | 0.0706*** (0.0038) |
feduyear | 0.0095*** (0.0029) | 0.0063** (0.0030) | 0.0082*** (0.0021) | 0.0079*** (0.0021) | 0.0078*** (0.0021) |
female | −0.2149*** (0.0166) | −0.2370*** (0.0190) | −0.2248*** (0.0125) | −0.2301*** (0.0128) | −0.2299*** (0.0128) |
age | 0.0158*** (0.0039) | 0.0113*** (0.0035) | 0.0142*** (0.0026) | 0.0141*** (0.0026) | 0.0138*** (0.0026) |
wexp | −0.0017 (0.0034) | 0.0011 (0.0031) | −0.0005 (0.0023) | −0.0003 (0.0023) | −0.0003 (0.0023) |
marry | 0.1471*** (0.0170) | 0.1156*** (0.0198) | 0.1351*** (0.0130) | 0.1349*** (0.0129) | 0.1346*** (0.0129) |
scale | 0.0004*** (0.0000) | 0.0004*** (0.0000) | 0.0004*** (0.0000) | 0.0005*** (0.0000) | 0.0005*** (0.0000) |
TJAN | −0.0503*** (0.0066) | −0.0519*** (0.0078) | −0.0502*** (0.0050) | −0.0503*** (0.0050) | −0.0507*** (0.0050) |
TJUL | 0.0874*** (0.0159) | 0.1035*** (0.0166) | 0.0933*** (0.0115) | 0.0899*** (0.0115) | 0.0907*** (0.0115) |
workhour_alt | −0.0045*** (0.0011) | −0.0042*** (0.0011) | |||
unem_alt | −0.0238* (0.0137) | −0.0170 (0.0137) | |||
year | 0.0158** (0.0061) | ||||
_cons | 2.7904*** (0.4185) | 2.3943*** (0.4370) | 2.6150*** (0.3026) | 3.5419*** (0.3666) | −28.3320** (12.4421) |
2293 | 1742 | 4035 | 4035 | 4035 | |
0.349 | 0.361 | 0.357 | 0.359 | 0.360 |
Note: Standard errors in parentheses,
From Table 3, we can see that, in both years, workers with higher job risks are compensated with higher wages, indicating that risk is a disamenity. Similarly, July temperature is a disamenity, and workers engaged with higher July temperature are paid more. At the same time, January’s temperature is an amenity, and workers are willing to sacrifice some wages for a warmer winter. Both industry unemployment and workhour have a negative and significant coefficient. The workers’ individual attributes have expected effects on wages. For example, senior married male workers with a higher education (or the respondent’s father has a higher education, higher
Given the estimation results of the hedonic wage model, we can measure the marginal willingness to pay for one unit of risk reduction (1/1000,000) as follows:
The estimated MWTP from both discrete choice models and hedonic wage models are calculated and transferred to US dollars at the exchange rate of 30 TWD: 1 USD, as shown in Table 4.
MWTP for risk reduction (safety) by the magnitude of 1/1000,000 (unit: USD)
ML | Model 1 | 1885 | 1537 | 2233 |
Model 2 | 2152 | 1798 | 2506 | |
PML | Model 3 | 3022 | 2739 | 3305 |
Model 4 | 2963 | 2672 | 3253 | |
HWM | FE | 25 | 13 | 36 |
The MWTP estimated from the two mixed logit models are comparable to each other but are significantly larger than the MWTP from the hedonic wage model. In fact, the MWTP estimated from the discrete choice model is unreasonably larger than any related studies in Taiwan or abroad. For example, Zhang et al. (2022) found a VSL of $14 million based on Taiwan labour market data during 1999 and 2014. Banzhaf (2022) conducted a meta-analysis using the results of five meta-analyses about the US and found a median VSL of $7 million, with a 90% confidence interval of $2.4 to $11.2 million. Based on the stated preference method, the OECD estimate of VSL is about $4 million (OECD, 2012). Giergiczny, M. (2008) estimated the VSL for Poland and found a value between $0.79 and $2.41 million. VSLs estimated in mid- or low-income countries are generally lower.
Given the linear utility function assumed in the discrete choice model, the nonmarginal value of risk reduction can be calculated by multiplying the changes in risks by the MWTP; thus, the unreasonably large MWTP from the discrete choice model also implies an unreasonably large nonmarginal value of risk reduction. Therefore, we believe the hedonic wage model outperforms the discrete choice model in evaluating safety with labour market data.
One possible explanation for the surprisingly large MWTP estimates by the discrete choice model stems from the well-acknowledged non-existence of moments of a ratio distribution resulting from dividing two normally distributed variables. As we know, the MWTP of risk is measured as the absolute value of the marginal utility of risk (
Another possible explanation of the extremely large MWTP from the discrete choice model is that job choices are actually not very responsive to wages. In our discrete choice model results, the coefficients of wages are quite small. Though they are statistically significant, they suggest that wages do not have a large effect on workers’ industry choices. In our case, the wage varies across individuals rather than industries, which could cause the workers’ industry choices to be insensitive to wages.
The two approaches differ in their underlying assumptions and theoretical foundations. The hedonic wage method assumes a competitive market with numerous heterogeneous firms and consumers, while the discrete choice model typically assumes a known utility function that is linear in individual and job or housing attributes. The hedonic model results from consumers’ utility maximisation and firms’ profit maximisation, while the random utility model focuses solely on consumer behaviour (Jonker, 2001). Despite these differences, there is a connection between the two models. Wong (2010) demonstrates a duality between the hedonic price model and the discrete choice model: the gradient of the hedonic price function represents the ratio of a weighted average of individuals’ marginal utilities, where the weights are derived from choice probabilities in the discrete choice logit model.
Compared to the hedonic wage model, the discrete choice model has two widely recognised disadvantages, aside from the issue of non-existent moments in the WTP ratio distribution. First, the hedonic price equation reflects market equilibrium that balances consumers’ willingness to pay and firms’ marginal costs, while the discrete choice model only captures the demand side. This may explain why the discrete choice model often yields higher WTP estimates than the hedonic price model. For example, Palmquist and Israngkura (1999) analyse MWTP for air quality improvements using the same housing market data with both models. They find that the discrete choice model produces larger estimates. Similarly, Sinha et al. (2021) compare the two approaches in evaluating MWTP for climate attributes and find that the discrete choice model generates MWTP estimates for warmer winters that are twice as large as those from the hedonic price model.
A second disadvantage of the discrete choice model is that it relies heavily on assumptions about the utility function form and the distribution of the random term, which are, unfortunately, restrictive and hard to test (Freeman et al., 2014). Moreover, most studies adopting the discrete choice model in environmental goods valuation (Chay and Greenstone, 2005; Bayer et al., 2009; Freeman et al., 2019) have adopted a multinomial logit estimation procedure that is subjected to the IIA property. The IIA property imposes a strict substitution pattern so that introducing a third option does not change the ratio of the choice probabilities between two alternatives – a condition rarely met in real-world scenarios.
This is the first study to apply the discrete choice model to real labour market data to investigate the value of job safety and compare the results with those from the hedonic wage model. This study finds that the hedonic wage model performs better than the discrete choice model in modelling real labour market decisions and provides a more reliable marginal willingness to pay (MWTP) for job safety. Future research should further explore the comparison between these two approaches using real market data or simulation in both the housing and labour markets regarding both the marginal value and nonmarginal value.