Investor-State Dispute Settlement and the Future of the Precautionary Principle
Publié en ligne: 31 déc. 2016
Pages: 449 - 486
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1515/bjals-2016-0016
Mots clés
© 2016 Haydn Davies
This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 3.0 License.
Free trade agreements can be traced back to the ancient empires which existed before the Common Era.(1) However, the heyday of trade expansion came in the nineteenth century when the transport innovations of the industrial revolution, combined with Empire, and an adherence to laissez-faire economics - particularly in Great Britain - opened up enormous trade opportunities across the world.(2) An early example of bilateralism, which featured the now-familiar most favoured nation status, was the Cobden-Chavalier agreement of 1860 between Great Britain and France. This led to a series of similar European agreements which created something of a golden era of trade in Europe. Unfortunately this was short-lived; an economic depression in the 1870s ushered in a period of increasing protectionism which was ultimately to lead to great instability and nationalism culminating in a half-century of economic and military conflict in the twentieth century.(3) Following World War II, the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade - the first major multilateral trade agreement and the forerunner of the WTO(4) - was created in 1948, having been salvaged from the failed attempt to create an international trade organisation at a conference of states in the Cuban capital in 1947.(5)
GATT, and later, the WTO, facilitated the growth of the global economy in the later twentieth and twenty-first centuries, and offered an independent dispute settlement service in the form of the WTO’s dispute settlement body and appellate panel. These offered a means of settlement of trade disputes that avoided, initially at least, some of the political and diplomatic hurdles presented by state-state negotiation. However, the WTO seems to have become a victim of its own success. Viviane de Beaufort takes the view that despite its considerable success in attempting to broker agreements between 159 states, progress at the WTO has foundered on: “confrontations between states”; the increasingly complex nature of the negotiations which have moved from concerns with tariffs to complex technical matters such as phytosanitary protection and intellectual property; and the rise of “concerns on sovereignty.” (6) As a result multilateralism on the WTO model has suffered a decline in popularity originating in “a general lack of enthusiasm from states and … WTO governance issues.” (7) Consequently states have moved towards bilateral or multilateral free trade agreements, including the recent so-called Mega-Treaties, brokered without direct input from the WTO. A number of such agreements also contain provisions on investment and these tend to follow established patterns in bilateral investment treaties (BITs), and commonly define the terms for investments between states, make provision for most-favoured nation status, define what is meant by fair and equitable treatment, prohibit expropriation and may even make provision for dispute settlement, which may permit an investor to sue a host state directly.
In recent times, the United States has been particularly active in embracing this model of trade and, since its first free trade agreement with Israel in 1985, is now party to 20 free trade agreements,(8) including the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA),(9) and the recently concluded Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP).(10) It is also a party to 42 bilateral investment treaties(11) as well as 52 trade and investment framework treaties.(12) While the use of BITs by the United States may appear impressive it is dwarfed by Germany’s 135 (of which 32 are in force) and the United Kingdom’s 106 (96 in force). In fact, the proliferation of this type of agreement worldwide has been such that the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development puts the current number of BITs at 2948, of which 2317 are in force.(13) The proliferation of BITs was near-exponential between 1970 (five agreements) and the peak in 1996 (221 agreements). Since then, the scope for new BITs has declined with only 11 BITs concluded in 2013.(14)
This increase of BITs and investment chapters in free trade agreements is coupled with a spectacular increase of case load in investor-state dispute settlement (ISDS) fora. The last summary of the case load statistics for the International Centre for the Settlement of Investment Disputes (ICSID) indicated that 52 applications were currently registered. Just a decade earlier, in 2005, the figure was approximately half that (at 27 applications), and in 1995 was a mere three applications.(15) In the years 1972 to 1994, ICSID applications totalled only 32; by December 2015 this total had risen to 549. This has occurred against the background of a rise in preference for arbitration generally as evidenced by the growth in other arbitral fora. (16)
The reasons for the rise in popularity in BITs and the introduction of investment chapters in free trade agreements, particularly the recent Mega-Treaties are not difficult to find. There are distinct advantages to states in brokering agreements directly and, as Caroline Foster has pointed out, such agreements “encourage and support international commercial private actors’ freedoms to invest, disinvest, repatriate capital, buy and sell goods and services, employ, navigate, exploit communal resources, and take business decisions.”(17) As such, both developing and developed states favour investment agreements; developing states, because they facilitate foreign direct investment, and developed states, because they offer an attractive trading platform for private actors - invariably economically important multinational corporations - amongst others, with the introduction of an ISDS mechanism which avoids the diplomatic and political vagaries of state-state settlement‥
However, there are some distinct disadvantages to ISDS. In particular, it permits aggrieved investors to take host states directly to international arbitration; it is not necessarily the case that the investor need first exhaust domestic remedies,(18) especially if they consider that seeking such remedies might be futile.(19) Once at ICSID, or a similar forum, the nature of the ISDS that follows is profoundly different from normal “private” arbitration, in that one of the parties (the state) is constrained by public interest considerations that do not affect the other. This use of arbitration has been described as “internationalized public law”(20) and, in effect, takes the established principles of domestic public law and places them in an international arbitration forum which is not necessarily well suited for the purpose. Arbitration was developed for private investors as a relatively swift alternative to contentious litigation where the remedy was decided according to the dictates of commercial expediency and with a view to maintaining the commercial relationship. The rules of natural justice, due process,
The paper will examine just one aspect of ISDS, but one which has profound implications for regulatory sovereignty in nation states. At issue is the question of whether BITs and investment chapters in recent Mega-Treaties permit investors to challenge regulatory decisions on the basis,
However, rather than discuss this issue in purely abstract and theoretical terms, an attempt has been made to analyse the possibilities through a real-life and current issue, namely the European Commission’s restriction on the use of neonicotinoid insecticides. Hence this paper will assess what the possibilities might be were an investor to challenge this restriction under the terms of the proposed (though partly hypothetical)(27) investment chapter of TTIP and to reach some tentative conclusions on the reality of the threat to regulatory sovereignty in respect of the precautionary principle.
The European Commission has been at great pains to reassure concerned parties (including the “European Parliament, Member States, national parliaments and stakeholders”(28)) that any ISDS arrangements in TTIP will not affect regulatory sovereignty. In its press release in September 2015 on new proposals for an “Investment Court System for TTIP and other EU trade and investment negotiations” it reassured readers that “governments’ right to regulate would be enshrined and guaranteed in the provisions of the trade and investment agreements.”(29)
The Commission was perhaps well-advised to issue this reassurance since scrutiny of the operation of investment chapters in existing agreements, by analysis of the arbitral decisions that have emerged from them, could lead an analyst to a rather different conclusion. This Part will examine the general nature of the protections for environmental regulatory sovereignty in typical investment agreements, proposed and extant, before examining, in Part III, some of the arbitral decisions which have engaged with these types of provisions.
Modern model investment treaties such as the 2012 U.S. Model BIT(30) contain, at least on the face of it, built-in protection of the ability of states to regulate without interference from external investors. For example, Article 12 of the 2012 U.S. Model BIT concerns “Investment and Environment” and makes impermissible any attempts by states to:
waive or otherwise derogate from or offer to waive or otherwise derogate from its environmental laws … in a manner that weakens or reduces the protections afforded in those laws, or fail to effectively enforce those laws through a sustained or recurring course of action or inaction, as an encouragement for the establishment, acquisition, expansion, or retention of an investment in its territory.(31)
This recognises the well-established fact that weakening environmental regulatory standards can have the effect of distorting trade and seeks to avoid a race to the bottom in terms of environmental protection.(32)
The 2012 U.S. Model BIT also recognises the sovereignty of states in promulgating environmental regulation. Article 12(5) states that:
Nothing in this Treaty shall be construed to prevent a Party from adopting, maintaining, or enforcing any measure otherwise consistent with this Treaty that it considers appropriate to ensure that investment activity in its territory is undertaken in a manner sensitive to environmental concerns.(33)
Thus treaties based on the 2012 U.S. Model BIT not only attempt to protect the sovereignty of states in maintaining, adopting and enforcing environmental regulation but also ensure that states do not weaken protection in order to attract investment.
The Comprehensive Economic and Trade Agreement (CETA) between Canada and the European Union, concluded in September 2014,(34) is viewed by many as presaging the likely final contents of the TTIP and has drawn on existing model BITs (including the 2012 U.S. Model BIT) for many of its provisions.(35) CETA makes provision for investment protection(36) which is similar to existing model BIT texts, though the investment chapter was significantly modified following legal analysis such that:
Canada and the EU will strengthen the provisions on governments’ right to regulate; move to a permanent, transparent, and institutionalised dispute settlement tribunal; revise the process for the selection of tribunal members, who will adjudicate investor claims; set out more detailed commitments on ethics for all tribunal members; and agree to an appeal system.(37)
Hence the principal changes to the investment chapter in CETA were to create a bespoke Tribunal and Appellate Tribunal for the purposes of investor-state dispute settlement, including bespoke rules for the appointment of members of the arbitration and appellate tribunals. This is in contrast to the original text of CETA which drew on the existing services of ICSID. The new version makes use of certain of the rules of the ICSID Convention and of the ICSID Secretariat’s services but the arbitration hearings themselves will take place outside the ICSID system. This change was made to assuage some of the concerns, particularly in Europe, over the appointment and independence of ICSID arbitrators and the unavailability of appeal against ICSID arbitration decisions under Article 53(1) of the ICSID Convention.
In terms of CETA’s protection of environmental regulation in state parties’ territories, the investment chapter makes several concessions. Under Section B of CETA (Market Access),(38) the following do not constitute a denial of market access for the purposes of investment:
a measure concerning zoning and planning regulations affecting the development or use of land, or another analogous measure … a measure seeking to ensure the conservation and
Similarly, for the purposes of Section D of CETA (Investment Protection),(40) which includes the provisions for fair and equitable treatment, compensation, expropriation, transfers and subrogation, (41) a clarification is included at the beginning of the section:
For the purpose of this Chapter, the Parties reaffirm their right to regulate within their territories to achieve legitimate policy objectives, such as the protection of public health, safety,
The recently agreed TPP uses similar language in its investment chapter in relation to performance requirements:
Provided that such measures are not applied in an arbitrary or unjustifiable manner, or do not constitute a disguised restriction on international trade or investment, paragraphs 1(b), 1(c), 1(f), 2(a) and 2(b) shall not be construed to prevent a Party from adopting or maintaining measures, including environmental measures:
necessary to secure compliance with laws and regulations that are not inconsistent with this Agreement; necessary to protect human, animal or plant life or health; or related to the conservation of living or non-living exhaustible natural resources.(43)
In relation to the TPP investment chapter as a whole, a general provision is included in Article 9.15:
Nothing in this Chapter shall be construed to prevent a Party from adopting, maintaining or enforcing any measure otherwise consistent with this Chapter that it considers appropriate to ensure that investment activity in its territory is undertaken
The latest text of the investment chapter of the putative TTIP - though evidently incomplete(45)- is very similar to that of CETA, and also makes provision for a bespoke “Tribunal of First Instance” and a “permanent appeal Tribunal” for investor-state dispute settlement.(46) It also contains articles, like CETA, relating to fair and equitable treatment, compensation, direct and indirect expropriation, transfers, subrogation and denial of benefits.(47)
Very similar protections for important public interest matters are to be found in other, more established, trade agreements such as the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) and these, unlike the texts of CETA, TTP and TTIP,
Nothing in this Chapter shall be construed to prevent a Party from adopting, maintaining or enforcing any measure otherwise consistent with this Chapter that it considers appropriate to ensure that investment activity in its territory is undertaken The Parties recognize that
On the face of it such provisions should prevent interference with the environmental regulatory sovereignty which states must exercise in the public interest and prevent the dismantling of existing regulation as a means of attracting foreign direct investment. However, the reality has not always reflected these expectations. Some arbitral decisions have suggested that investor interests can, in certain circumstances, outweigh the right of a state to exercise sovereignty. It is to these decisions that we now turn.
Most ISDS proceedings have taken place under the auspices of the ICSID and a number of these have involved challenges based on attempts - at least on the face of it - to protect the environment or to preserve local sovereignty in respect of activities perceived to be environmentally unacceptable or contrary to local or national public health imperatives.
Perhaps the most controversial of these was the
Article 1105(1):
Each Party shall accord to investments of investors of another Party treatment in accordance with international law, including fair and equitable treatment and full protection and security.
…
Article 1110:
No Party may directly or indirectly nationalize or expropriate an investment of an investor of another Party in its territory or take a measure tantamount to nationalization or expropriation of such an investment (“expropriation”), except:
for a public purpose; on a non-discriminatory basis; in accordance with due process of law and Article 1105(1); and on payment of compensation
…
In short, the U.S. and Canadian investors in Metalclad were seeking to show that the lack of transparency in the operation of the Mexican regulatory system relating to hazardous waste sites, and the decision of the local municipality to create a nature reserve which included the entire site (thereby rendering it inoperable), amounted to a lack of fair and equitable treatment and to measures tantamount to expropriation.
The decision in relation to Article 1105(1) was based on the fact that there was considerable uncertainty on the part of the Mexican federal, state and municipal authorities as to which of them was in fact responsible for the permitting of hazardous waste facilities.(52) Metalclad had legitimately, and in good faith, relied on federal assurances about the legality of the construction and operation of the site. The absence of regulatory clarity, and uncertainty as to practice and procedure at the various levels of governance amounted to a lack of transparency. Given the strength of local opposition(53) it is perhaps understandable that the municipal authority so assiduously tried to prevent construction and operation of the plant. Nonetheless, the uncertainty unquestionably affected Metalclad’s ability to make decisions about, and to realise, their investment. The fact that ultimately this uncertainty resulted in an arbitral decision which compensated foreign investors at the expense of local autonomy may be seen as unfortunate, but Metalclad’s treatment
However, aspects of the panel’s comments on the Article 1110 infringement were much more controversial. Much of the decision appeared to follow logically from the Article 1105 finding, on the basis that such a degree of opacity in the regulatory and legal process was not only unfair and inequitable treatment, but on such a serious scale as to qualify also as a measure tantamount to expropriation. However, the panel went further and considered the state governor’s decision to issue an Ecological Decree which encompassed the site as part of the Article 1110 analysis:
… the Tribunal also identifies as a further ground for a finding of expropriation the Ecological Decree issued by the Governor of SLP on September 20, 1997. This Decree covers an area of 188,758 hectares within the “Real de Guadalcazar" that includes the landfill site, and created therein an ecological preserve. This Decree had the effect of barring forever the operation of the landfill.(54)
…
The Tribunal need not decide or consider the motivation or intent of the adoption of the Ecological Decree. Indeed, a finding of expropriation on the basis of the Ecological Decree is not essential to the Tribunal’s finding of a violation of NAFTA Article 1110. However, the Tribunal considers that the implementation of the Ecological Decree would, in and of itself, constitute an act tantamount to expropriation.(55)
This was to attract considerable informed criticism and adverse judicial treatment in the aftermath. Many commentators considered that the Tribunal - which was led by no less a figure than Professor Sir Elihu Lauterpacht, CBE, QC - had construed the term “indirect measures tantamount to expropriation” unacceptably widely and in such a way as to trespass on the legitimate exercise of state sovereignty in environmental matters. Professor Phillipe Sands has characterised the Tribunal as taking “a very broad approach to the definition of expropriation”(56) and has written elsewhere that such decisions represent a worrying and retrograde development in the requirement to balance the interests of investment with those of environmental protection.(57)
The decision received judicial scrutiny at the hands of Judge David F. Tysoe of the Supreme Court of British Columbia.(58) He reviewed the reasoning of the Tribunal and concluded that the
Turning to the question of whether the passing of the Eco-Decree amounted to a measure tantamount to expropriation, Tysoe, J. was not able to conclude that the Tribunal had been patently unreasonable in reaching its decision. However, he did conclude that the definition of expropriation used by the Tribunal was “sufficiently broad to include a legitimate rezoning of property by a municipality or other zoning authority.”(62) However, given that the definition used was a matter of law, the resulting conclusion was one with which Tysoe J. was “not entitled to interfere under the International CAA.”(63)
The importance of the
What then, is the legacy of the
It is worth noting, however, that not long after the
And yet, barely three years after
The
The
Expropriation also arose in the case of
IT IS HEREBY DECREED:
Article 1.- The municipal operating license granted by Municipal Resolution No. 6856-98-MDCH to Lucchetti Perú S.A. for its industrial plant situated at an unnumbered location on Avenida Prolongación Defensores del Morro, 20.5 km along the Panamericana Sur highway, Chorrillos, for the manufacture and sale of pasta is hereby revoked.
Article 2.- The industrial establishment referred to in the preceding article shall be closed and entirely removed; this shall be done within a maximum of twelve months from the day following the publication of this Decree.
Evidently this entirely “closed and … removed” the factory - a clearer example of expropriation would be difficult to imagine. However, given that it was for the purposes of environmental protection (i.e. in the public interest) and appeared nondiscriminatory in the sense that all outlets in that area were similarly affected, it would have been interesting to see how the Tribunal would have approached it. In the event Lucchetti’s claim failed on technical grounds(72) and the expropriation issue was never dealt with so we can only speculate on whether the
In 2012, the
However, more recently still, the
In a long and often difficult appraisal,(79) the Tribunal eventually turns to the question of fair and equitable treatment(80) and invokes the “transparency” analysis used in
The
Venezuela was also on the receiving end of another huge expropriation award at the end of 2014 in
All these decisions were the result of disputes which went all the way to full assessment of the merits of the parties’ positions and at least each party’s position was fully pleaded. However, there are instances where the threat of ISDS proceedings appear, at least on the face of it, to have resulted in a “chilling” of regulatory measures without the benefit of detailed argument. The use of threatened proceedings to influence the exercise of regulatory sovereignty has caused even more disquiet, not least because it is difficult, if not impossible, to assess the extent of its influence.
One of the starkest examples of this “use” of ISDS is the 1998
In the event, however, the merits of the claim were never addressed as the Canadian Government instead reached an out of court settlement with Ethylcorp, doubtless owing to lack of confidence that it could win on the merits in another arbitral forum. Though this response cannot be thought of as a classic regulatory chilling in that the provision was promulgated and remained in place after the challenge rather than preventing its genesis in the first place, it does illustrate that even where a public health measure is put in place for entirely
Thus there is plenty of precedent for the use of threats of arbitration to control regulation deemed to be economically threatening to an overseas investor. This gives rise to the question of whether regulatory measures adopted to protect public health or the environment in the European Union might potentially be open to challenge under the putative investment chapter of the TTIP by investors based in the U.S. Self-evidently the answer is yes by virtue of the mere existence of the investment chapter. However, there is an added nuance to challenges to environmental measures in the European Union since so many of them are based on the precautionary principle. It is contended that the different perceptions of this principle on both sides of the Atlantic presents an avenue of attack on regulatory measures in the European Union. Challenges to regulatory measures may be undertaken on the basis that the precautionary principle may be a disproportionate and non-scientific response which results in regulation based on fear and irrationality not on sound science.(92) It is to this debate that we now turn.
The precautionary principle is, in essence, the idea that lack of scientific uncertainty about a potentially harmful phenomenon, product or process should not, of itself, be a barrier to the taking of precautionary measures. The origins of the principle are somewhat obscure but it is generally traced back to Swedish and German environmental policies (Vorsorgeprinzip) of the 1970s. It has also been said to have been highly influential at the London Dumping Conference of the International Maritime Organisation in 1972, which gave rise to the Convention on the Prevention of Marine Pollution by Dumping of Wastes and Other Matter (MARPOL) which marked the beginning of the precautionary approach to the disposal of waste at sea.(93) Certainly by 1992 the precautionary approach was a significant element of international environmental policy and was prominent in the Declaration of the United Nations Conference on the Environment and Development, 1992 (Rio Conference):
In order to protect the environment, the precautionary approach shall be widely applied by States according to their capabilities. Where there are threats of serious or irreversible damage, lack of full scientific certainty shall not be used as a reason for postponing cost-effective measures to prevent environmental degradation.(94)
By 1998, the precautionary principle had become part of the legal order of the European Communities by virtue of the Treaty of Amsterdam 1997, which inserted a new Article 131(2) into the Treaty on European Union; essentially the same text is now incorporated in Article 191 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union which states that:
Union policy on the environment shall aim at a high level of protection taking into account the diversity of situations in the various regions of the Union. It shall be based on the precautionary principle and on the principles that preventive action should be taken, that environmental damage should as a priority be rectified at source and that the polluter should pay.(95)
Unfortunately the principle itself is not further defined in the Treaty. Some clarification is contained within the official “Communication from the Commission on the precautionary principle” of 2000(96) which indicates that the principle should be engaged:
… where preliminary objective scientific evaluation, indicates that there are reasonable grounds for concern that the potentially dangerous effects on the environment, human, animal or plant health may be inconsistent with the high level of protection chosen for the Community.(97)
However, the Communication also points out that
The precautionary principle should be considered within a structured approach to the analysis of risk which comprises three elements: risk assessment, risk management, risk communication.
The precautionary principle is particularly relevant
The precautionary principle, which is essentially used by decision-makers in the management of risk, should not be confused with the element of caution that scientists apply in their assessment of scientific data.
Recourse to the precautionary principle presupposes that potentially dangerous effects deriving from a phenomenon, product or process have been identified, and that scientific evaluation does not allow the risk to be determined with sufficient certainty.
The implementation of an approach based on the precautionary principle should start with a scientific evaluation, as complete as possible, and where possible, identifying at each stage the degree of scientific uncertainty.(98)
Thus the operation of the precautionary principle is envisaged as part of a wider risk assessment strategy where there is evidence that the risk exists, but the magnitude of that risk cannot be quantified with certainty. It is perhaps unfortunate that the term “sufficient certainty” in paragraph three of this extract receives no further elaboration particularly as it is in the response to the lack of sufficient certainty by policy and lawmakers that the controversy surrounding the precautionary principle inheres. The literature devoted to the general nature of the precautionary principle, the disagreement about its use, role and implementation across the Atlantic, and its role within trade law is voluminous(99) and the difference in transatlantic approaches to the principle is one of the sticking points in the negotiation of the TTIP itself.(100)
On the whole law- and policy-makers in the United States take a negative view of the precautionary principle(101) and this view has affected trade relations between the United States and the European Union in the past where fundamental differences have arisen in the response to unquantified risk. The United States (often joined by Canada, but also frequently supported by Australia, Brazil and New Zealand) has tended to prefer a cost-benefit approach to risk, taking the view that this is a more rational and scientific approach to risk management. The European Union, on the other hand takes a more precautionary approach based, as its foundational treaty requires, on the precautionary principle - a concept seen as irrational, post-enlightenment and risk averse by many in North America.(102) In crude terms these two approaches may be thought of as the innocent-until-proven-guilty and guilty-until-proven-innocent models respectively. This difference in views has underpinned the protracted trade disputes between North America and Europe over the licensing of genetically modified organisms(103) and the use of growth hormones in beef.(104) However, despite the commonly asserted difference in approaches between North America and Europe, which has to some extent been perpetuated above, it is necessary to bear in mind that the situation is far more complex than a simple divergence of opinion across the Atlantic. Bergkamp and Smith’s comprehensive analysis of the approach to precaution between the United States and the European Union is at pains to point out that both jurisdictions have embraced, and continue to embrace, precautionary regulation,(105) that the extent of the precaution taken is highly dependent on the issue under discussion,(106) and that each jurisdiction is at different stages of development in terms of its sophistication. However, they conclude that Europe, at least in 2013, remained the less sophisticated jurisdiction:
We regard the current EU penchant for indiscriminate use of the precautionary principle - in place of factual support or structured analysis of why it is “worth it” to society to act in the face of uncertainty - as probably a passing phase, reflecting the current lack of sophistication by the European public, national politicians, and judges in making rational risk choices, coupled with aggressive, opportunistic special pleading to take advantage of the current situation by environmental NGOs and some sections of domestic EU industry and agriculture.(107)
Of course a European may justifiably express some scepticism of this conclusion in the face of U.S. attitudes to the uncertainty relating, for example, to climate change among certain influential members of the U.S. polity who ignore the science altogether in favour of leftist conspiracy theory.(108)
Whatever the realities of implementation, the difficulties with the precautionary principle as a concept are not scientific in origin. There is general consensus and mutual respect between U.S. and European scientists in relation to the scientific method itself, and hence in relation to the degree of uncertainty associated with a particular phenomenon, product or process. Disagreement emerges in relation to the most appropriate
Hence disagreement over approaches to precaution are disagreements over doctrinal interpretation rather than over science or law as such. It is this that makes regulations based on the precautionary principle peculiarly vulnerable to attack in arbitral proceedings, since arbitrators are asked to rule, not so much on the quality of the science underpinning a regulation or even the act of regulation itself (though this is sometimes challenged), but rather the
An illustrative example of the operation of the precautionary principle in the European Union is to be found in regulations that implement the current partial restriction of the use of a class of chemicals known as the neonicotinoid insecticides (hereinafter neonics). Developed in the 1980s, principally by the chemical companies Bayer, Syngenta and Sumitomo Chemical, the neonics are a class of systemic insecticides (taken up by all parts of the plants to which they are applied), which attack the central nervous systems of pest insects which feed on the plants with fatal effect, but with none of the environmental persistence or high mammalian toxicity associated with the previous pyrethrin, pyrethroid, organophosphate and organochlorine alternatives.(113) The background to the imposition of the current restrictions on the use of these chemicals has been fully described elsewhere(114) and only a brief summary is necessary here.
Initially, Council Directive 91/444/EEC(115) (concerning the placing of plant protection products on the market) made provision for substances to be added to Annex 1 of that directive which listed “Active Substances Authorized for Incorporation in Plant Protection Products.” Subsequent secondary legislation added a number of neonics to this Annex thereby permitting their use in plant products in the European Union.(116) However, following accidental releases of these chemicals which resulted in the deaths of bee colonies, the use of the neonics clothianidin, thiamethoxam, imidacloprid and fipronil were subjected to additional risk assessment requirements.(117) Subsequent regulatory amendments placed still further restrictions, specifically on the use of three of the more commonly used neonics, clothianidin, thiamethoxam and imidacloprid, as foliar treatments, as soil additives and in seed dressing.(118)
These restrictions were justified on the basis of a report, commissioned by the European Commission,(119) by the European Food Safety Authority which reviewed the evidence on the effect of neonics on bee colonies.(120) The evidence suggested that although the normal use of these pesticides was not lethal to bees, there was some evidence that neonics residues have the effect of interfering with the bees’ navigation systems, thereby disorientating them and preventing them from returning to their colonies or from indicating the sources of food to the remainder of the colony even were they able to return. The European Food Safety Authority recommended that further evidence was required in order to establish the magnitude of the risk.(121) On this basis the Commission, taking the precautionary approach required by Article 191 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union, and explicitly referred to in EU Regulation (EC) No 1107/2009, recommended restrictions on the use of neonics.
These recommendations were viewed with some equivocation in the member states of the European Union(122) and the arable farming community has protested that the restrictions on the application of neonics are significantly adversely affecting their business.(123) In 2015 the National Farmers’ Union successfully applied to the UK Government for an emergency lifting of the ban in three eastern counties of England, a move which was unsuccessfully challenged by Friends of the Earth.(124)Perhaps unsurprisingly the chemical industry has viewed these restrictions as being an overreaction based on flawed field studies.(125)
The central regulation which introduced these restrictions, EU Regulation (EC) No. 1107/2009, is explicitly based on the precautionary principle.(126) Article 1(4) states:
The provisions of this Regulation are underpinned by the precautionary principle in order to ensure that active substances or products placed on the market do not adversely affect human or animal health or the environment. In particular, Member States shall not be prevented from applying the precautionary principle where there is scientific uncertainty as to the risks with regard to human or animal health or the environment posed by the plant protection products to be authorised in their territory.
The question is whether - should the TTIP come into being in anything like its current form - Bayer, Syngenta or Sumitomo could seek to challenge the restriction under the terms of the TTIP draft investment protection section(127) on the basis that the restrictions represent a failure to accord fair and equitable treatment or that the restrictions represent an expropriation of property.
Clearly the first requirement is that the said corporations are investors as defined in the TTIP. The current version of the TTIP draft investment chapter published by the EU Commission defines the term “investor” as “a natural person or a juridical person of a Party that seeks to make, is making or has already made an investment in the territory of the other Party.”(128) Certainly the corporations would meet this requirement since all have offices in the United States.(129) There is certainly no requirement that the nationality of the investor be defined by reference to the domicile of the parent company, though the terms of the investment chapter in the governing treaty would be relevant and could, conceivably, contain such a requirement. However, the chances of such a restrictive trade requirement successfully becoming part of a final investment text are very slim and highly unlikely to be included in the final text of the TTIP. No such requirement appears in the TPP, the CETA or any of the treaties with which the author is familiar. The TPP defines an “investor of a Party [to be] a Party, or a national or an enterprise of a Party, that attempts to make, is making, or has made an investment in the territory of another Party.”(130) CETA - likely to be more representative of the final text of TTIP given that the European Union is a party - is more prescriptive and defines an investor as:
… a Party, a natural person or an enterprise of a Party, other than a branch or a representative office, that seeks to make, is making or has made an investment in the territory of the other Party;
For the purposes of this definition, an an enterprise that is constituted or organised under the laws of that Party and has substantial business activities in the territory of that Party; or an enterprise that is constituted or organised under the laws of that Party and is directly or indirectly owned or controlled by a natural person of that Party or by an enterprise mentioned under paragraph (a)(131)
In general arbitral panels have taken a generous view of relationships between subsidiary and parent companies in establishing the existence of “substantial business activities”(132) and it is unlikely that the corporations would have any difficulty in establishing their status as U.S. investors for the purposes of the TTIP.
It would then need to be established that the licensing and marketing of neonics in the European Union is a covered investment.
A “covered investment” is “an investment which is owned, directly or indirectly, or controlled, directly or indirectly, by investors of one Party in the territory of the other Party made in accordance with applicable laws …”(133) The fact that the imposition of the neonics restrictions would obviously predate the TTIP (should it ever be signed and ratified) would not be a barrier since the definition of “covered investment” includes an investment “whether made before or after the entry into force of this Agreement.”(134) Thus the definition of a covered investment would be retrospective and cover all the contentious trade disputes extant at the time of the signing of TTIP (not only the neonics dispute but other, more long-standing ones such as the beef hormones and GMOs disputes).(135)
An “investment” is defined in the TTIP draft investment protection section as:
… every kind of asset which has the characteristics of an investment, which includes a certain duration and other characteristics such as the commitment of capital or other resources, the expectation of gain or profit, or the assumption of risk. Forms that an investment may take include:
an enterprise; shares, stocks and other forms of equity participation in an enterprise; bonds, debentures and other debt instruments of an enterprise; a loan to an enterprise; any other kinds of interest in an enterprise; an interest arising from:
a concession conferred pursuant to domestic law or under a contract, including to search for, cultivate, extract or exploit natural resources, a turnkey, construction, production, or revenue-sharing contract, or other similar contracts; intellectual property rights; any other moveable property, tangible or intangible, or immovable property and related rights; claims to money or claims to performance under a contract;
For greater certainty, ‘claims to money’ does not include claims to money that arise solely from commercial contracts for the sale of goods or services by a natural person or enterprise in the territory of a Party to a natural person or enterprise in the territory of the other Party, domestic financing of such contracts, or any related order, judgment, or arbitral award.
Returns that are invested shall be treated as investments and any alteration of the form in which assets are invested or reinvested shall not affect their qualification as investments.(136)
It is submitted that the corporations would have little difficulty in establishing ownership or control of investments in Europe under many of these headings (which are in any case not exhaustive) by virtue of their supply and licensing of insecticides in the European Union. In any event it has been noted elsewhere that “there has been a tendency to extend the meaning of investment in treaties.”(137)
Article 1 of the TTIP draft investment protection section sets the jurisdictional scope of the section relating to investment protection as including “(i) covered investments, and (ii) investors of a Party in respect of a covered investment as regards any treatment that may affect the operation of such investment.”(138)Interpretation of the term “any treatment that may affect … investment” by a court or tribunal would probably be undertaken by reference to principles of international investment law, where a measure (such as the neonics restriction) imposed by a government must have a “legally significant connection” to an investor.(139) This requirement derives largely from the interpretation of Article 1101 of the NAFTA(140)and is said to have arisen to limit claims to principal investors only and to prevent ancillary claims by suppliers, subcontractors and so forth.(141) Arguably, however, the draft TTIP criteria of “any treatment” by a host Party is far wider than the equivalents in NAFTA, CETA and TPP which relate to “measures … adopted or maintaine”(142) and it is submitted that the corporations would have little difficulty in establishing the requisite legal significance since the restrictions imposed by the EU Commission are aimed
Having established standing it would then be necessary for the corporations to establish that the EU Regulations restricting the use of neonics in some way contravenes the investment protection measures guaranteed by Chapter II, section 2 of the TTIP. This section contains provisions relating to investor treatment and protection. Previous arbitration decisions suggest that a challenge to the neonics restrictions are most likely to succeed under the fair and equitable treatment and expropriation provisions.
Fair and equitable treatment provisions in the TTIP draft investment protection section appear at Article 3, paragraph 2 and state that:
A Party breaches the obligation of fair and equitable treatment … where a measure or a series of measures constitutes:
denial ofjustice in criminal, civil or administrative proceedings; or fundamental breach of due process, including a fundamental breach of transparency and obstacles to effective access to justice, in judicial and administrative proceedings; or manifest arbitrariness; or targeted discrimination on manifestly wrongful grounds, such as gender, race or religious belief; or harassment, coercion, abuse of power or similar bad faith conduct; or a breach of any further elements of the fair and equitable treatment obligation adopted by the Parties in accordance with paragraph 3 of this Article.(144) When applying the above fair and equitable treatment obligation, a tribunal may take into account whether a Party made a specific representation to an investor to induce a covered investment, that created a legitimate expectation, and upon which the investor relied in deciding to make or maintain the covered investment, but that the Party subsequently frustrated.(145)
It is possible that the corporations could argue, based on the uncertainty of the evidence that led to the imposition of the neonics restrictions, that the imposition amounts to manifest arbitrariness.(149) Admittedly this would be difficult if solely reliant on demonstrating that the restrictions were capriciously imposed, though counsel for the corporations may get a little further if they attempted to equate arbitrariness with inconsistency, unpredictability and irrationality, thereby appealing to the vast body of opinion that suggests that adherence to the precautionary principle is indeed irrational, unpredictable, anti-scientific and, thus, arbitrary. This argument could be further bolstered by the “legitimate expectation” provision in Article 3, paragraph 4 if it could be argued that the initial inclusion of neonics in Annex 1 of Directive 91/444/EEC and then EU Regulation (EC) No. 1107/2009 amounted to a “specific representation”, which the subsequent restrictions - based as they were on the precautionary principle - “frustrated.”(150) In the
So far as is relevant for present purposes, Article 5 of the TTIP draft investmen protection section makes the following provision:
Neither Party shall nationalize or expropriate a covered investment either directly or indirectly through measures having an effect equivalent to nationalisation or expropriation (hereinafter referred to as ‘expropriation’) except:
for a public purpose; under due process of law; in a non-discriminatory manner; and against payment of prompt, adequate and effective compensation.(153)
This text is supplemented by Annex 1 - which expands on the interpretation of article 5 - and includes a definition of direct and indirect expropriation,(154) as well as indicating that, in determining whether a measure is an indirect appropriation, account is to be taken of the economic impact, duration and character of the measure.(155) Most significant for this discussion is the provision that:
For greater certainty, except in the rare circumstance when the impact of a measure or series of measures is so severe in light of its purpose that it appears manifestly excessive, non-discriminatory measures of a Party that are designed and applied to protect legitimate public welfare objectives, such as the protection of public health, safety,
The regulations restricting the use of neonics comply with the criteria in paragraphs (a) to (c) of Article 5, but since (presumably) the corporations have not been compensated in respect of the restrictions on neonics, then the measures could amount to an expropriation of the corporations’ investments under Article 5(d). Since they are clearly not a direct expropriation - not involving “[a] formal transfer of title or outright seizure”(157) - then they can only amount to an indirect expropriation as “substantially depriv[ing] the investor of the fundamental attributes of property in its investment, including the right to use, enjoy and dispose of its investment, without formal transfer of title or outright seizure.”(158)
However, since these measures have clearly been “designed and applied to … the protection of [the] environment,” then they should be safe from attack as indirect expropriation measures, in reliance on Annex 1, paragraph (3) unless it could be shown that the restrictions are “so severe in light of [their] purpose that [they appear] manifestly excessive.” This is potentially the avenue by which the precautionary basis of the measures could be attacked by the investor corporations. Again, the paucity of the evidence of cause and effect between the normal use of neonics and the effect on bee geolocation could be used to argue that the regulatory response is manifestly excessive and hence tantamount to an indirect expropriation.
In the
Before leaving the … the Tribunal’s view that under NAFTA, lawmakers in Canada and the other NAFTA parties can set environmental standards as demanding and broad as they wish and can vest in various administrative bodies whatever mandates they wish. Errors, even substantial errors, in applying national laws do not generally, let alone automatically, rise to the level of international responsibility vis-à-vis foreign investors. The trigger for international responsibility in this particular case was the very specific set of facts that were presented, tested and established through an extensive litigation process.
This view - particularly the first sentence - were it to become universal among arbitrators (of which, of course, there is no guarantee given the absence of the doctrine of the arbitrary, capricious, and illegal revocation of the Enterprise’s valuable right to mine for oil and gas under the St. Lawrence River by the Government of Quebec without due process, without compensation, and with no cognizable public purpose.(167)
This was in response to Quebec’s imposition of a moratorium on fracking - a precautionary measure with many counterparts in Europe.
The final draft of the environment chapter of the TTIP is not yet available,(168) so it is not yet possible to ascertain the extent to which precautionary measures may be offered protection. Thus far, no specific protection of the precautionary principle has been included in any of the draft texts which have been released. There is provision for the precautionary principle - though not under that name - in the CETA, which is the only other “North American” free trade agreement which the European Union has entered into thus far.(169) There are two specific chapters in the CETA related to environmental protection - Chapter 24 (Trade and the Environment) and Chapter 25 (Trade and Sustainable Development). Under Article 24.8.2:
The Parties acknowledge that where there are threats of serious or irreversible damage, the lack of full scientific certainty shall not be used as a reason for postponing cost-effective measures to prevent environmental degradation.(170)
This apparent protection for the precautionary principle suggests a model of precaution much closer to the North American cost-benefit approach(171) than the EU notion of precaution which underpins the neonics restrictions. The requirements for either “serious” or “irreversible” damage closely reflects the text of Principle 15 of the Rio Declaration,(172) with no apparent concession to the more precautionary approach commonly referenced in European law.(173) Should the same text appear in the TTIP (assuming the negotiations do reach a conclusion), it is suggested that they would not necessarily protect the Commission’s regulatory precautions on neonics since it is eminently possible to argue that the threat posed by neonics - based on the available evidence - is neither serious nor irreversible.
One of the most controversial aspects of the TTIP negotiations over the investment chapter is the perception that unaccountable arbitrators in investment-state disputes will be in a position to dictate to sovereign states over matters which have traditionally been considered the sole preserve of national regulatory authorities or legislators. To address this concern the European Commission has issued - as part of the draft investment services document - proposals for the setting up of an independent arbitral tribunal and appeal tribunal for Europe.(174) These proposals are closely modelled on the WTO Appellate body and it is hoped(175) that this will address the criticisms raised in the past,(176) the “fundamental lack of trust”(177) in arbitral tribunal decisions, and in particular the vexed questions of lack of legal training,(178) independence,(179) the lack of avenues for appeal,(180) and the lack of transparency.(181)
However, whilst these measures (in the perhaps unlikely event that they are accepted by the United States) will doubtless improve the quality and legitimacy of arbitral decisions, it is questionable whether they would affect an assessment of the precautionary principle in any substantive sense. The tribunal will still be an
As already discussed, what is known of the TTIP text already offers ample potential for challenges to regulations based on the precautionary principle. This potential, it is suggested, will not be materially affected by the make-up or procedures of the tribunal panel itself.
As this paper was being completed, the TTIP negotiations entered their 15th round(182)against the backdrop of recent demonstrations in Germany against both TTIP and CETA.(183) The EU Commission will no doubt be even more conscious of the need to reassure European citizens that TTIP will not undermine national sovereignty - a message that has assumed even greater importance since the citizens of the United Kingdom voted in favour of “Brexit” in a referendum in July 2016. The “Leave” campaign in Britain made much of the need to “regain sovereignty” from the European Union,(184) so that questions of national sovereignty are now, more than ever at the forefront of politicians’ minds in the EU.
Where environmental sovereignty is concerned the text of the TTIP includes, at first sight, quite strongly worded provisions to permit nation states to maintain and enhance environmental protection. However, very similar provisions to these appear in other investment and trade agreements but they have not necessarily prevented investors from seeking compensation for the loss of their investment (or the value of it) as a result of local, regional or national measures designed to protect the environment or public health. Such claims have invariably been based on the fair and equitable treatment principle and/or on the basis that the measures represent measures tantamount to (indirect) exropriation. It is also the case that such claims do not necessarily need to reach the merits stage in order to bring about the desired effect as illustrated in the
The current text of the TTIP does not suggest that it is likely to be significantly more resilient to such claims than many of its forbears. In fact, given that so much of the regulation in environmental matters and public health in the European Union is based on a version of the precautionary principle which is far more “precautionary” than envisaged in principle 15 of the Rio Declaration, investor claims which seek to attack its rationality are probably more likely.
Of course the final version of the TTIP may contain explicit protection for the precautionary principle, but, if this merely repeats the provision in CETA, then it is unlikely to prevent claims based on equivocal scientific evidence such as the restrictions currently in place for neonicotinoid pesticides. Moreover, the provision of a bespoke tribunal and appeal system within TTIP may not necessarily make claims founded on the irrationality of regulatory responses to the precautionary principle any less plausible or any more likely to fail.
Investment protection agreements have the potential to enhance environmental protection if they encourage greater transparency of regulation by the host state so that the investor is certain about the regulatory environment into which they are entering and know the risks. However, the approach of investment tribunal panels themselves needs to change in order to take a broader view of purposes of arbitration in an era of climate change, loss of biodiversity and the need to preserve ecosystem services. It can no longer be appropriate merely to consider the private property rights of investors as the
World Trade Organisation, World Trade Report 2011, 49,
Which replaced GATT in 1995.
Viviane de Beaufort,
For a list of the U.S. free trade agreements
North American Free Trade Agreement, US-Can.-Mex., Dec.17, 1992, 32 I.L.M 289 (1993),
A conglomerate of 12 states: Australia, Brunei, Canada, Chile, Japan, Malaysia, Mexico, New Zealand, Peru, Singapore, USA and Vietnam. At the time of writing TPP is yet to be ratified. Trans-Pacific Partnership text released Jan. 26, 2016 following legal scrub,
For a list of U.S. bilateral investment treaties, see
For a list of U.S. trade and investment framework treaties,
Figures compiled from data from the ICSID Database of Bilateral Investment Treaties,
By way of illustration, business of the International Court of Arbitration of the International Chamber of Commerce has grown from 529 cases in 1999 to 801 in 2015 [
Caroline Foster,
E.g. Article 26 of the ICSID Convention states that “A Contracting State
Foster,
For example, the award in
Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (Consolidated Version), 2008 O. J. (C 115), 47, art. 191(2).
Pressure from a centre-left coalition of members of the European Parliament resulted in the postponement of a vote on TTIP in the EU Parliament in June 2015 owing to the vast number of tabled amendments [
The putative text of the TTIP is not generally made available to interested parties outside the EU Commission and the U.S. State Department. However, the European Commission has recently redrafted the proposed investment chapter and published it online, albeit in different stages of completion,
Press Release, European Commission, Commission Proposes New Investment Court System for TTIP and other EU Trade and Investment Negotiations, IP/15/5651 (Brussels, Sept. 16, 2016),
2012 U.S. Model Bilateral Investment Treaty,
Though it must be said that this protection is a relatively recent addition to the U.S. Model BIT and this provision does not feature in the older BIT agreements entered into by the United States,
Though still to be signed and ratified by the parties as of June 10, 2016. The document has undergone legal analysis in the European Union, the text of which was released in December 2015 [
Cf. 2012 U.S. Model Bilateral Investment Treaty,
Comprehensive Economic and Trade Agreement,
Joint statement by Cecilia Malmström, EU Commissioner for Trade, and Chrystia Freeland, Minister of International Trade of Canada, Feb. 29, 2016,
Comprehensive Economic and Trade Agreement,
Trans-Pacific Partnership,
E.g. there are references to National Treatment and Most Favoured Nation Status at Annex II (Public Debt) to section 2, paragraph 2,
North American Free Trade Agreement,
Mexico was able to take advantage of this procedure by virtue of Article 1120(1)(b) of the NAFTA, to which Mexico is a signatory. At the time of writing Mexico remains a non-signatory to the ICSID Convention.
Philippe Sands, Lawless World 133 (2005).
Philippe Sands,
It was stated earlier that arbitration under the ICSID Additional Facility rules are not subject to Article 53(1) of the ICSID Convention (which forbids appeals against decision made under the ICSID Rules) and hence may be appealed in a suitable national court. Thus because the Metalclad arbitration had been held in Vancouver, the Supreme Court of British Columbia had jurisdiction to hear the appeal under the terms of British Columbia’s International Commercial Arbitration Act, R.S.B.C. 1996 c. 233.
Though it should be noted in passing, in the interests of balance, that the tribunal’s award of US$16.7m against Mexico represented only 18.5% of the original claim of US$90m Metalclad’s projected profits were not awarded on the basis,
Though in recent times there is a marked preference for full publication, probably in the interests of transparency and in an attempt to improve the public perception of the legitimacy of the decisions.
See
The dispute between the Peruvian authorities and Lucchetti was considered to have started before the bilateral investment treaty between Chile and Peru came into force and hence did not fall within its terms. Article 6 of the Peru-Chile Bilateral Investment Treaty is concerned with expropriation in similar, though not identical, terms to NAFTA Article 1110,
Philippe Sands,
Mobil Investment Canada Inc. & Murphy Oil Corp. v. Venezuela,
As of July 19, 2016, there are 24 pending cases against Venezuela at ICSID alone - despite its withdrawal from the ICSID Convention in 2012. It has already faced 16 previous (concluded) cases.
Nicolas Kozloff, Hugo ChÁvez: Oil, Politics and the Challenge to the US (2007). This is one of scores of texts on
Occupying some 242 pp.
Though the original claim was for $1,735,124,200. Id. ¶ 5.
Agreement on Encouragement and Reciprocal Protection of Investments (22 October 1991) between the Kingdom of the Netherlands and the Republic of Venezuela.
Note however, that the production and use of MMT
Manganese-based Fuel Additives Act, S.C. 1997, c.11 (Can.).
The precautionary principle has been described in the U.S. as a “paralyzing principle” (Cass R. Sunstein,
Kevin Stairs & Peter Taylor,
United Nations, Report of the United Nations Conference on the Human Environment, Stockholm, 5-16 June 1972 (United Nations publication, Sales No. E.73.II.A.14 and corrigendum), chap. I, Principle 15.
Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (Consolidated Version), supra, note 24, art. 191(2).
Communication From the Commission on the Precautionary Principle, Commission of the European Communities, COM(2000) 1 final
It has been suggested that the term “precautionary approach”- widely preferred in the United States - reflects a preference, rather than a binding principle, John S. Applegate,
The history of the approaches to precaution on each side of the Atlantic and a comprehensive review of the recent policies in the two trading blocs may be found in Lucas Bergkamp & Turner T. Smith,
Lucas Bergkamp & Turner T. Smith,
Lucas Bergkamp & Turner T. Smith,
Lawrence Kogan & Lucas Bergkamp,
Nicholas A. Ashford,
Lawrence Kogan & Lucas Bergkamp,
UNESCO/COMEST, The Precautionary Principle 17ff (United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organisation 2005).
Alberto Allemano,
Council Directive 91/444/EEC, 1991 O.J. (L 230), 1.
Commission Directive 2006/45/EC, 2006 O.J. (L 130), 27; Commission Directive 2007/6/EC, 2007 O.J. (L 43), 13; Commission Directive 2008/116/EC, 2008 O.J. (L 337), 86.
Commission Directive 2010/12/EU, 2010 O.J. (L 65), 27.
Directive 91/444/EEC was repealed and replaced by eu Regulation (EC) No. 1107/2009 (2009 O.J. (L 309), 1), which in turn was implemented by EU Regulation (EC) No. 540/2011 (2011 O.J. (L 153), 1), the effect of which was to place further restrictions on the use of neonics. Finally EU Regulation (EC) No. 485/2013 (2013 O.J. (L 139), 12) took restrictions still further. For greater detail
Question No. EFSA-Q-2012-00556, approved on 31 May 2012.
European Food Safety Authority,
At the March 2013 meeting of the Standing Committee of the Food Chain and Animal Health - the body with responsibility for advising the Commission on plant product safety - 27 representatives of the member states failed to reach the qualified majority vote required to recommend the restrictive proposal put before them. Thirteen countries voted in favour of the proposal, nine against, and five abstentions. A similar split occurred in a subsequent appeal. Owing to this failure, the Commission was then able to put forward its own proposal. For a more detailed discussion of the process
Emma Downing,
TTIP, Draft Chapter on Trade in Services, Investment and E-Commerce, art. 1-1(3) (q),
Syngenta is a Swiss parent company but has regional offices in Durham and Greensboro, North Carolina, as well as in Minnesota and Nebraska, United States. Similarly, Bayer, though a German parent company, has a U.S. office in Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania. In fact, Bayer’s U.S. presence may be set to become even bigger with rumours of a takeover bid for the Monsanto Corporation. If permitted by the U.S. authorities this would give Bayer an estimated 40% share of the agricultural chemicals and biotech market in the U.S. alone (BBC Radio Four, Today Programme, 0620h, Wed. Sep. 7, 2016). The Sumitomo Corporation is a Japanese parent company, but the Sumitomo Corporation of the Americas has offices all over the US, including New York, Illinois, Colorado, Minnesota, Texas, California, Oregon and Washington D.C.
Trans-Pacific Partnership,
Comprehensive Economic and Trade Agreement,
TTIP, draft investment protection section,
TTIP draft investment protection section,
Muthucumaraswamy Sornarajah, International Law on Foreign Investment, 16 (3d ed., 2010).
TTIP draft investment protection section,
Which sets the scope of the investment chapter of NAFTA as limited to “measures adopted or maintained by a Party
For extensive discussion of the notion of “measures … adopted or maintained” in the context of NAFTA, Article 1101
TTIP draft investment protection section,
The NAFTA states that: Each Party shall accord to investments of investors of another Party treatment
Partick Dumberry,
Arbitrary: 1. Dependent on will or pleasure … 2. Based on mere opinion or preference as opposed to the real nature of things; capricious, unpredictable, inconsistent. The New Shorter Oxford English Dictionary, 107 (Lesley Brown, ed., vol. 1 A-M, 1993).
TTIP draft investment protection section,
Strictly speaking a draft is available (
Some references to “precaution” do appear in the early 1600 pages of the agreement, but these are exclusively related to intellectual property protection in chapter 20.
Comprehensive Economic and Trade Agreement,
United Nations,
Communication from the Commission,
TTIP draft investment protection section,
Mojtaba Dani & Afshin Akhtar-Khavari,
TTIP draft investment protection section,
Though admittedly this was mostly in the context of the rather narrow question of the freedom of movement of persons.