Long-term unemployment remains a persistent challenge for European labor markets. Despite the economic recovery between 2014 and 2020, long-term unemployment remains stubbornly high. In 2018, across the 28 member states of the European Union (EU-28), 42.9% of jobseekers were unemployed for >12 months.
Eurostat (indicator: une_ltu_a), accessed April 2020.
A popular way to fight (long-term) unemployment is the use of hiring subsidies (European Commission [EC], 2019). The countries of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) spend 0.08% of their gross domestic product (GDP) on recruitment incentives, which amounts to 15% of total spending on active labor market programs (ALMPs).
We are grateful to the OECD for sharing these data. The OECD (2019a) report provides more details of the potential of the Labour Market Policy (LMP) database to study policies targeted at the LTU; the OECD (2019b) report provides an in-depth evaluation of ALMPs targeted at the LTU in five countries. The OECD defines a long-term unemployed jobseeker as a jobseeker with a continuous spell of unemployment lasting at least 1 year.
This study aims at evaluating the effect of a hiring subsidy in Belgium targeted at jobseekers who have been unemployed for at least 6 months and are between 45 years and 48 years old. This is not the first study that aims at evaluating the impact of such hiring subsidies (see, e.g., Sjögren and Vikström, 2015; Ciani See, e.g., Jacobson
Within the literature evaluating time-limited in-work benefits at the supply side, it is commonly agreed that human capital does not improve by providing short-term work experience to low-skilled welfare recipients, inhibiting thereby enduring positive effects on employment and earnings (Blundell, 2002, 2006; Card and Hyslop, 2005; see Van der Linden, 2021, for a survey).
See Riddell and Riddell (2014, 2020) for criticism on this view.
We find that the hiring subsidy increased the job-finding rate by 13%. However, we also find that the effect on employment dissipates gradually and becomes zero after 1 year. Hence, the hiring subsidy does not create long-lasting stable employment. The effect on employment is larger and more persistent for high-educated jobseekers with at least a bachelor's degree, but the positive effect also gradually declines over time, suggesting that for this group also, it does not extend beyond the expiration of the subsidy. For low-skilled mid-career workers, the level of the wage subsidy may not be high enough to compensate for the loss in firm-specific human capital induced by the job loss. However, we argue that high-educated workers have acquired sufficient transferable skills to be hired in short-lived jobs with limited skill requirements. Such jobs can be made acceptable and/or profitable as long as the hiring subsidy is paid out, but not beyond this period. The finding that most of the effect is induced by hiring by temporary work agencies reinforces this interpretation and is in line with the evidence that the employment offered by these agencies is no stepping stone to more stable employment (Autor and Houseman, 2010; Givord and Wilner, 2015).
Our findings align to a large extent with the literature on the impact of recruitment subsidies for LTU workers. While most of these studies focus on jobseekers unemployed for at least 12 months, this literature nevertheless offers the most relevant reference point. The target group considered in our study consists of jobseekers unemployed for at least 6 months, a group that arguably shares many characteristics with jobseekers unemployed for 12 months.
The literature on hiring subsidies for older (long-term unemployed) workers is less relevant since these studies focus on jobseekers aged >55 years (Boockmann
The systematic reviews of Vooren
Three more recent studies, not included in the aforementioned reviews but closely related to our work, provide further evidence that hiring subsidies targeted at the LTU have positive effects. Sjögren and Vikström (2015) report positive effects of a hiring subsidy in Sweden targeted at jobseekers unemployed or out of the labor force for at least 1 year. Importantly, this is one of the few studies that examine the impact of recruitment subsidies on employment stability.
There is some evidence that hiring and wage subsidies can have long-lasting positive effects. Saez
Apart from considering a different target population and examining employment stability, our study contributes to the literature in a few other respects. First, our study differs from a methodological perspective in that we rely on a triple-difference identification strategy and that we evaluate the effectiveness of the policy by studying its abolishment rather than its introduction. Furthermore, we study spillover effects. Scholars have criticized microeconometric evaluation studies on the grounds that they fail to take into account general equilibrium effects and that a positive employment effect for the target group may merely reflect a countervailing effect on the ineligible population (Crépon
The paper is organized as follows. The next section (Section 2) discusses the Belgian institutional setting and the recent labor market reforms. Section 3 describes the data from the Flemish public employment service (PES). Section 4 outlines the triple-difference approach. Next, in Section 5, we discuss the effect of abolition of the hiring subsidy on transition to employment and on employment stability and thereafter examine effect heterogeneity. The final section (Section 6) concludes.
Belgium is one of the few countries where unemployment insurance (UI) is not time limited, although the benefit level decreases over time. UI amounts to 65% of the (capped) gross wage
The cap decreases with duration of unemployment. In January 2022, it decreased from about €2,900/month during the first 6 months, over €2,700/month during the next 6 months to €2,520/month (€2,470/month for singles living without dependents) when unemployed for >1 year. ( In January 2022, this floor per month was €622 for cohabitants without dependents, €1,198 for singles living alone, and €1,478 for individuals in charge of dependents (children or partner without household income). These lump sum amounts also define floors below which benefits cannot drop (
Since UI is not time limited, many jobseekers registered at the Vlaamse Dienst voor Arbeidsbemiddeling en Beroepsopleiding (VDAB) (the Flemish PES) are LTU. In 2019, nearly two thirds of the 184,851 jobseekers were unemployed for >6 months, while half of these were unemployed for >1 year (Figure 1). From 2014 until the outbreak of the coronavirus disease-2019 (COVID-19) pandemic in March 2020, the number of jobseekers continuously decreased.
Figure 1
The evolution of long-term unemployment in Flanders.

It is well-known that the share of the LTU among the unemployed population increases during economic booms and decreases during economic recessions (Machin and Manning, 1999). This regularity also holds in Flanders. All jobseekers benefited from the economic recovery from 2014 to 2019, but the positive impact was less pronounced for the LTU. In 2019, 65% of the jobseekers were unemployed for >6 months, up from 62% in 2015. Figure A1 in Appendix A shows that a similar pattern emerges when restricting the population to jobseekers aged 40–48 years. As we will explain in section 4, the procyclical behavior of long-term unemployment is the main reason why we opted for a triple-difference evaluation strategy rather than a more standard difference-in-differences (DiD) approach.
The Flemish PES has specific policies, such as training programs and job counseling, tailored to the needs of the LTU (Desiere
These programs are unlikely to interfere with the evaluation of the hiring subsidy targeted at jobseekers unemployed for >6 months. First, similar programs have existed before and after the abolition of the subsidy as this aspect of active labor market policies was already a regional competence before the reform. Second, the PES defines a “long-term unemployed jobseeker” as a jobseeker who is unemployed for at least 1 year. Our analysis focuses on jobseekers unemployed for 1–12 months. These jobseekers were not eligible for specific programs aimed at the LTU.
Until a few years ago, the PES applied specific rules when activating and monitoring jobseekers older than 50 years of age. Moreover, this group was eligible for a more generous hiring subsidy until 2014. We restrict the population to jobseekers aged 40–48 years to avoid the possibility that these specific policies for older jobseekers interfere with our evaluation of the hiring subsidy. The PES did not have specific programs in place aimed at jobseekers aged 40–48 years over the entire period considered in the analyses.
Similar to the hiring subsidies, job search monitoring also has become a regional competence and has been subsequently reformed. Since 2016, job search monitoring in Flanders is the competence of the PES and no longer that of a separate federal institution. It is unlikely that the reform of the job search monitoring interferes with the evaluation of the abolition of the hiring subsidy because job search monitoring already occurred before the reform, was not – or, at best, only gradually – intensified after the reform, and did not specifically target jobseekers unemployed for >6 months.
In 2014, wage and hiring subsidies targeted at disadvantaged groups became a regional competence. All four Belgian regions subsequently reformed and simplified the complex existing federal system of wage and hiring subsidies and substantially reduced the number of eligible groups. Flanders opted to abolish all hiring subsidies targeted at the LTU. This paper focuses on the abolition of the hiring subsidy targeted at jobseekers older than 45 years of age who were unemployed for at least 6 months over the past 9 months. After the reform, jobseekers in Flanders aged 25–55 years and unemployed for <12 months were no longer eligible for any hiring subsidy.
The other regions also abolished this specific hiring subsidy, but, in contrast to Flanders, introduced hiring subsidies for jobseekers unemployed for at least 12 months. These hiring subsidies do not depend on the jobseeker's age.
Until January 1, 2017, employers hiring older, LTU jobseekers were entitled to a quarterly Social Security contribution (SSC) reduction of €1,000 during the first five quarters, followed by a quarterly reduction of €400 during the subsequent 16 quarters. Hence, the total maximum hiring subsidy amounted to €11,400 over 21 quarters. The subsidies were reduced (almost proportionally) for employees working part time. In contrast to many other hiring subsidies studied in the literature, no specific conditions were attached to receiving this subsidy: employers were free to offer open-ended or temporary contracts; were not obliged to offer training; did not have to retain the worker for a minimum number of months or offer a nonsubsidized job after the subsidy expired.
The hiring subsidies were not automatically awarded to the employers. Eligible jobseekers had to obtain a certificate from a federal institution proving their eligibility. Employers could then use this certificate to obtain SSC reductions. Eligible individuals (or their employer) could still apply for this certificate after they had been hired, but the subsidies were not granted retrospectively. Given data limitations, the take-up rate of the hiring subsidy is unknown, but the take-up rate of similar SSC reductions is estimated to be approximately 70% (Boucq and Novella, 2018; Desiere
From January 1, 2017, no new certificates were awarded to Flemish jobseekers, in effect abolishing the hiring subsidy in Flanders. The subsidies granted under the federal rules were gradually phased out. Jobseekers who had obtained a certificate before January 1, 2017, remained eligible for the hiring subsidy until the certificate expired. Employers who had hired an eligible jobseeker continued to receive subsidies until the end of 2018.
In the last quarter of 2016, 2,564 individuals benefited from the hiring subsidy in Flanders, of whom 369 individuals were hired in that quarter. The average, quarterly subsidy amounted to €506, while the total yearly cost of the policy amounted to €5.3 million in 2016.
The median full-time equivalent gross monthly wage (which excludes SSC paid by the employer) of individuals hired with a subsidy is €2,324 and ranges for half of these employees between €1,981 (3rd quartile) and €2,796 (1st quartile). Their income is lower because only one out of four individuals works on a full-time basis. Taking the aforementioned interquartile range as a measure of spread, the abolition of the subsidy increased labor costs by 11%–16% during the first five quarters after being hired and by at most 6% during the 16 subsequent quarters.
These estimates do not take into account the so-called “tax shift”, which gradually reduced employers’ SSC, particularly for low-wage workers (irrespective of their prior unemployment duration or age), from 2016 to 2019. The tax shift partially offsets the negative impact of the abolition of the hiring subsidy on labor costs.
Although the hiring subsidy was not targeted at temporary help agencies, these agencies seem to use this subsidy more intensively for hiring than firms that hire workers directly without the intermediation of such agencies. Between 2015 and 2016, 61% of the LTU aged 45–48 years hired with a subsidy were hired by temporary help agencies (Table A1 in Appendix A). The second most important sector, the cleaning sector, only accounts for 5% of the hires. A representative survey conducted among employers in Flanders in 2016 finds that about 42% of all recruitments are achieved through the mediation of temporary help agencies (Delagrange and Notebaert, 2018, p. 79).
There are two potential reasons why temporary help agencies make more intensive use of the hiring subsidy than firms that directly hire workers. First, as temporary help agencies are specialized in the hiring of workers, they are much better informed about the myriad of hiring subsidies that are available in the Belgian labor market, and therefore, they are more likely to make use of them. For instance, surveys indicate that about 40% of the employers in Flanders are not aware of the existence of hiring subsidies for specific target groups (Boucq and Novella, 2018, p. 10). Second, the Flemish PES announces on its website its partnership with the sector of temporary help agencies and that it regards temporary jobs as “stepping stones” to regular work. This, together with anecdotal evidence that caseworkers of the PES advise unemployed jobseekers to accept temporary jobs (Cockx and Van Belle, 2019), can explain why jobseekers are more likely to be hired by temporary work agencies than by direct hiring firms.
The data set consists of all jobseekers who registered at the VDAB (the Flemish PES) between January 2012 and December 2018. The monthly labor market position of each jobseeker is known from registration until February 2019. This position is determined on the last day of each month. The administrative data distinguish several types of employment (e.g., sheltered work, part-time work in combination with unemployment benefits) that are linked to the administrative status of the jobseeker. The data set does not contain details on the sector of employment, the type of contract, the wage, or the number of days worked. We adopted VDAB's standard definition of employment but also considered a more stringent definition of work that excludes, among others, temporary help agency jobs lasting between 10 days and 20 days per month.
An unemployment spell starts in the month of registration at the PES and ends when the jobseeker resumes work. In the benchmark analysis, jobseekers who leave the labor force at a certain point in time are still considered unemployed.
We opted for this approach because jobseekers classified by the Flemish PES as “out of the labor force” might still be actively looking for a job, while jobseekers classified as “actively looking for a job” might in practice be out of the labor force.
The data set contains the socioeconomic characteristics of jobseekers, such as date of birth, level of education, language proficiency, and nationality. We restrict the population to jobseekers entitled to UI aged 40–48 years at the time of registration at the PES, excluding jobseekers aged 44 years. As we discuss in the next section (Section 4), the treatment group consists of LTU jobseekers aged 45–48 years, while jobseekers aged 40–43 years belong to the control group. Jobseekers aged 44 years are excluded from the sample because some of the jobseekers in this age group become eligible for the subsidy after being unemployed for 6–12 months.
Prior to the reform, jobseekers were eligible for a hiring subsidy after being unemployed for at least 6 months in the previous 9 months. Eligibility for a hiring subsidy is stipulated by law and closely monitored by a federal institution. Because we compare the job-finding rates of the short-term unemployed and the LTU, we have to identify the exact point in time that a jobseeker becomes eligible for a subsidy, but the time grouping of the unemployment data in months prevents us from determining this point for all jobseekers in the population. To address this issue, we retain in the sample only the individuals who were registered as employed for at least 4 consecutive months prior to registration at the PES. This restriction ensures that no selected jobseeker can become eligible for the subsidy with an elapsed unemployment duration of <6 months. This is because this restriction ensures that, at the time of registration, such workers can be unemployed at the most for 5 months in the previous 9 months, and that for each month following registration, the total time spent as unemployed can never exceed 5 months before the sixth month after registration. Hence, by restricting the data set to this subpopulation, we identify the impact of the policy on only jobseekers unemployed for at least 6 consecutive months.
This restriction implies that unemployment spells that started between January 2012 and April 2012 (i.e., the first 4 months in the data set) are discarded, because it cannot be checked whether these individuals were employed prior to registration at the PES. Of the remaining 189,154 unemployment spells, 14,556 spells are discarded because the labor market history in the past 4 months is not known, whereas 69,365 spells are discarded because the jobseeker did not work 4 consecutive months prior to registration.
The PES only registers someone's labor market position after an individual has registered at the PES. We discarded 14,556 spells because these individuals were not known by the PES prior to becoming unemployed. These individuals were (most likely) employed or out of the labor force prior to registration at the PES, and one could assume that these individuals only became eligible for the subsidy 6 months after registration. We nevertheless discarded this group because we could not explicitly check that this eligibility condition was met. In Table A5 in Appendix A, we show that the main findings hold when including this group. We also show that our findings are robust to including jobseekers who did not work 4 consecutive months prior to becoming unemployed.
The triple-difference identification strategy, discussed in Section 4, contrasts the job-finding rates of younger (40–43 years old) vs. older (45–48 years old) and short-term (unemployed for <6 months) vs. long-term (unemployed for 6–12 months) unemployed jobseekers, before and after the reform. Table 1 compares the characteristics of jobseekers by age group and unemployment duration before and after the reform. The pre-reform and post-reform periods contain jobseekers who registered at the PES before and after June 1, 2016, respectively. These statistics describe the profile of the target group and also allow us to test whether the composition of the population is stable before and after the reform, which lends credence to the triple-difference identification strategy.
Characteristics of jobseekers by age group and unemployment duration: Age group; Unemployment duration, before and after the reform
41.48 | 41.44 | 41.49 | 41.44 | 46.47 | 46.47 | 46.48 | 46.46 | 47.13 | 0.77 | |
54.12 | 54.77 | 54.76 | 54.10 | 53.80 | 54.84 | 54.83 | 54.13 | 56.84 | 0.43 | |
Low | 38.74 | 37.66 | 40.99 | 39.50 | 42.73 | 39.37 | 44.15 | 41.56 | 43.33 | −1.18 |
Medium | 39.69 | 39.01 | 38.72 | 37.59 | 37.47 | 38.53 | 36.41 | 37.10 | 43.73 | −0.08 |
High | 21.57 | 23.34 | 20.30 | 22.91 | 19.80 | 22.11 | 19.44 | 21.34 | 12.94 | 1.25 |
No | 1.26 | 2.80 | 1.35 | 2.83 | 1.07 | 2.58 | 1.20 | 2.71 | 2.22 | −0.05 |
Limited | 11.22 | 14.17 | 13.25 | 16.06 | 10.06 | 13.08 | 11.79 | 15.48 | 9.61 | −0.81 |
Good | 37.40 | 32.47 | 37.70 | 32.32 | 39.04 | 35.13 | 39.50 | 35.32 | 37.60 | −0.18 |
Excellent | 50.13 | 50.57 | 47.70 | 48.79 | 49.83 | 49.21 | 47.51 | 46.50 | 50.57 | 1.04 |
EU-15 | 74.46 | 68.08 | 70.33 | 63.86 | 80.16 | 73.80 | 76.42 | 70.15 | 77.97 | −0.17 |
EU-13 | 2.16 | 3.46 | 2.44 | 3.58 | 1.76 | 2.97 | 1.95 | 3.35 | 3.11 | −0.34 |
Other | 23.38 | 28.47 | 27.24 | 32.56 | 18.08 | 23.23 | 21.63 | 26.50 | 18.92 | 0.52 |
No. of individuals | 34,318 | 21,127 | 18,259 | 8,332 | 30,405 | 18,587 | 16,381 | 7,192 | 1,221 | – |
This column presents the characteristics of individuals aged 45–48 years hired with the subsidy analyzed in this paper, which is targeted at jobseekers older than 45 years of age and unemployed for at least 6 months, between the second quarter of 2015 and the last quarter of 2016 (pre-reform period). We do not have this information for jobseekers hired before 2015 because we obtained data from Flemish institutions that are in charge of this policy since 2015 and only have data since then. We excluded the first quarter of 2015 because we present the characteristics of the new hires, not of the population of subsidized employees at a given moment in time.
This column presents the coefficient of the triple-interaction term of regressing the jobseekers’ characteristics on group dummies (young vs. old; short-term unemployed vs. LTU jobseekers), period dummies (before vs. after the reform), and all the interaction terms. None of these triple-interaction terms is significant at the 10% level.
In general, jobseekers in both age groups have very similar characteristics and are vulnerable in several respects. About eight out of 10 jobseekers have at the most a lower-secondary (low) or an upper-secondary (medium) level of education; only about half report having an excellent proficiency in Dutch; and one out of five were born outside the EU-28.
Comparing the characteristics of short-term unemployed with those of LTU jobseekers within age groups shows that both before and after the reform, the LTU are generally more vulnerable than the short-term unemployed, but the differences are not particularly pronounced. In both periods and age groups, the LTU are more likely to have a low level of education and tend to be less proficient in Dutch.
We do not observe substantial differences within groups before and after the reform. The main difference within groups is that jobseekers in the pre-reform period are more likely to be born in the EU-15 and tend to be more proficient in Dutch.
To test whether the composition of the population is stable before and after the reform, we estimate a triple-difference regression, which consists in regressing the jobseekers’ characteristics on group dummies (i.e., older vs. younger jobseekers; and short-term unemployed vs. LTU jobseekers), period dummies (before vs. after the reform), and all the interaction terms between these dummies. The coefficient of the triple-interaction term, which is reported in the last column of Table 1, indicates whether the composition of the population has changed. All triple-interaction terms are small and insignificant at conventional levels, indicating that the composition of the population remained stable before and after the reform.
Table 1 also shows the characteristics of LTU jobseekers aged 45–48 years who have been hired with a subsidy. Individuals hired with the subsidy appear not to be “selected” based on observable socioeconomic characteristics. Jobseekers hired with a subsidy have similar characteristics as the LTU aged 45–48 years. If anything, individuals hired with a subsidy tend to have a lower level of education.
Descriptive evidence shows that subsidized jobs are not long-lasting ones. The share of employees for whom a subsidy was granted for several subsequent quarters quickly decreases with employment duration. About 70% of the individuals for whom a subsidy was granted in a first quarter also received a subsidy in the second quarter, while approximately 25% received a subsidy over four consecutive quarters. This illustrates that a large majority of subsidized jobs is destroyed after a few quarters.
Figure 2 explores the employment stability of individuals older than 45 years of age hired before the reform after being unemployed for 5 (full line) and 6 months (dashed line). Only individuals in the latter group are eligible for the subsidy. It shows the share of individuals employed for 1–65 consecutive months after being hired. Employment tends to be a short-lived process. Half of the individuals are employed for <10 consecutive months, while one in four is employed for at least 5 years. Although the differences are small and not statistically significant at conventional levels, the figure suggests that individuals hired without a subsidy have more stable employment spells than individuals hired with a subsidy. Individuals employed with and without a subsidy are equally likely to remain employed for 5 consecutive months. However, after being employed for 5 months, individuals employed with a subsidy are more likely to lose their job. However, this is just descriptive evidence that cannot be given any causal interpretation. In the next section (Section 4), we discuss the strategy that is followed to identify causal effects.
Figure 2
Employment stability: share of individuals aged 45–48 years hired in Month 5 (not eligible for the subsidy) vs. in Month 6 (eligible for the subsidy) employed for 1–65 consecutive months after being hired.

We aim at estimating the effect of abolition of the hiring subsidy on the transition to employment and on employment stability of LTU jobseekers. Our basic setup follows a triple-difference approach (Gruber, 1994; Cortes and Pan, 2013; Olden and Møen, 2020). This approach exploits differences in labor market prospects between short-term unemployed (unemployed for <6 months) and LTU jobseekers (unemployed for 6–12 months), across age groups (jobseekers aged 40–43 years vs. jobseekers aged 45–48 years
Jobseekers aged 44–44.5 years at the time of registration at the PES are excluded because these jobseekers are not yet eligible at the 6-month threshold, but they will become eligible after 6–12 months. Jobseekers aged 44.5–45 years belong in theory to the treatment group, as these jobseekers will be eligible after being unemployed for 6 months. We nevertheless excluded them because these jobseekers might be less aware of the existence of the subsidy or might be less likely to apply for a certificate immediately after turning 45 years old. Including the 44.5- to 45-year-old group in the treatment group does not alter the main findings (Table A6 in Appendix A).
The following linear probability model is estimated:
The subsidy was abolished on January 1, 2017. Jobseekers who registered at the PES in June 2016 are eligible for the hiring subsidy in December 2016. We nevertheless choose June 1, 2016, rather than July 1, 2016, as the cutoff date defining the pre-reform and post-reform periods, because jobseekers becoming eligible for the subsidy in December 2016 do not have much time to apply for the necessary certificates proving eligibility and are, therefore, unlikely to benefit from the subsidy. We show that the results are not sensitive to using a different cutoff. The results do not alter when controlling for the quarter (rather than year) of inflow in unemployment.
We examine employment outcomes for jobseekers unemployed for 1–12 months and censor unemployment spells after 12 months. We do not consider the employment prospects of jobseekers unemployed for >12 months because this group was eligible for even more generous hiring subsidies before the reform. By construction, unemployment spells of jobseekers in the pre-reform period never cross the reform date so that jobseekers in this group are never affected by the abolition of the subsidy.
The parameter of interest,
We estimate a triple difference, rather than a DiD, because the parallel trends of the DiD are rejected, as shown in Section 5.1. By contrast, the weaker identifying assumptions of a triple difference are not rejected. The identifying assumption of a triple difference is that the parallel trend in differences holds (Olden and Møen, 2020). In other words, in the absence of the treatment, the difference between the outcomes for long-term vs. short-term unemployed jobseekers younger than 45 years of age must trend similarly as the same difference for jobseekers older than 45 years of age. Importantly, the triple-difference estimator will not be biased if the business cycle affects the LTU differently than the short-term unemployed as long as the differential effect of the business cycle on short-term unemployed vs. LTU is similar for jobseekers younger and older than 45 years of age.
Our approach differs from the standard DiD and triple-difference method because we exploit the abolition of the subsidy to identify the average treatment effect on the treated (ATT) rather than exploiting the introduction of a subsidy, which is more common. In our setup, the control group is never treated (as is standard), while the treatment group is treated in the pre-reform period and is not treated in the post-reform period. The post-reform period is thus the period during which both the treatment and the control groups are not treated, while this state of the world typically occurs in the pre-reform period in the standard setting. This implies that the parallel trend assumption should hold in the post-reform period (when both groups are not treated) and not necessarily in the pre-reform period (when the treatment group is treated). We report placebo tests for the post-reform period. As an additional placebo test, we also examine whether the job-finding rate of the short-term unemployed remains unaffected by the reform.
One additional concern with our approach is bias due to dynamic sorting. The linear probability model is a robust estimator of the average partial effect in settings with discrete duration data (Angrist, 2001), but it only holds in the absence of unobserved individual effects (see, e.g., Farbmacher and Tauchmann, 2021). Unobserved individual effects cause dynamic sorting because individuals with a higher unobserved “ability” are more likely to quickly resume work and, hence, leave the sample. One way to test for the presence of unobserved individual effects is to check whether the grouped residuals are autocorrelated over time. Dynamic sorting leads to negative autocorrelation. We follow Cockx and Ridder (2001) and test for this autocorrelation based on the Breusch–Godfrey Lagrange multiplier (LM) test of autocorrelation.
Like in DiD specifications, substitution and anticipation effects can bias the triple-difference estimate. We examine whether (1) LTU jobseekers were hired at the expense of the short-term unemployed; (2) whether older jobseekers were hired at the expense of younger jobseekers; and (3) whether the last eligible cohorts of jobseekers were hired at the expense of the first ineligible cohorts.
We first examine the effect of the subsidy on the job-finding rate. In this case, the outcome variable,
After establishing the positive effect of the subsidy on the job-finding rate, we examine whether the subsidy created short-lived or long-lasting stable employment.
We do not observe job-to-job transitions without an intervening unemployment spell. For this reason, the paper focuses on employment stability, not on job stability or on job tenure. The indicator is only defined if the total time span is within the observed period, i.e., until February 2019. Hence, the regressions contain fewer observations when considering longer employment durations.
Given the setting, it would be natural to estimate the abolition of the subsidy in a DiD framework, contrasting either short-term unemployed to LTU older jobseekers, or jobseekers younger than to those older than 45 years of age among the LTU.
Figure 3 illustrates the former approach and shows the job-finding rate of jobseekers aged 45–48 years as a function of elapsed unemployment duration before and after the reform. The impact of the abolition of the subsidy appears evident. Due to the improved economic conditions, the job-finding rate is higher for the “control” unemployment durations in 2017 than in 2015, but the job-finding rate abruptly decreases in 2017 at the moment the jobseeker would have become eligible for the subsidy before the reform. Reassuringly, such a “jump” in the job-finding rate is not observed for jobseekers aged 40–43 years (Figure A2 in Appendix A), which suggests that the jump observed here can be attributed to the abolition of the subsidy.
Figure 3
Exploring the effect of the abolition of the subsidy in a DiD framework: the job-finding rate of jobseekers aged 45–48 years as a function of elapsed unemployment duration, before and after the reform.

Formal DiD estimates are reported in Appendix B. Contrasting short-term unemployed to LTU older jobseekers, as in Figure 3, suggests that the abolition of the subsidy decreased the job-finding rate by 3.52 pp [95% CI: −4.03 to −3.00]. The DiD model exploiting differences across age groups, rather than across unemployment duration, suggests that the abolition of the subsidy reduced the job-finding rate by 0.14 pp [95% CI: −0.62 to 0.34]. Hence, the abolition of the subsidy has a substantial negative effect (−38%
−38%=−3.52/9.2 (where 9.2% is the job-finding rate of jobseekers aged 45–48 years unemployed for 6 months who registered at the PES in 2017).
Appendix B presents placebo tests that reject the validity of both DiD approaches. The business cycle causes biases in both approaches in opposite directions. Economic upswings have a stronger positive effect on the short-term unemployed than on the LTU, a well-known finding in the literature (Machin and Manning, 1999). Hence, comparing the job-finding rates of short-term unemployed and LTU older jobseekers (as in Figure 3) overestimates the negative effect of abolition of the subsidy since it does not capture the information that, relative to the short-term unemployed, the job-finding rate of the LTU would have deteriorated anyway after the reform due to the improved economic conditions. At the same time, we find evidence that the job prospects of all jobseekers aged 45–48 years, including the short-term unemployed who were not affected by the reform, improved more than those of younger jobseekers after the reform, most likely because the improved economic conditions were more beneficial to older than younger jobseekers. Hence, contrasting the job-finding rate of younger to older LTU jobseekers underestimates the negative effect of the abolition of the subsidy.
The triple-difference approach captures these business cycle effects and avoids wrongly attributing them to the abolition of the subsidy. The weaker identifying assumption of a triple difference, as we show in Section 5.2, is not rejected. The first regression in Table 2 estimates the benchmark specification. The triple-interaction term in the first specification indicates that the abolition of the subsidy reduced the job-finding rate by 1.18 [95% CI: 0.48–1.88 pp]. This is a relatively large effect. Given that the job-finding rate after being unemployed for 6 months is 9.2% after the reform, the hiring subsidy increased the job-finding rate by 13% [95% CI: 5–20%]. We also tested whether the effect on the job-finding rate varied by unemployment duration (Table A6 in Appendix A). While the effect appears to decrease with unemployment duration, a formal
The impact of the abolition of the hiring subsidy on the job-finding rate: triple-difference estimates
− | − | − | − | ||
## Age 38 years | 0.00779** (0.00389) | ||||
## Age 39 years | 0.000466 (0.00394) | ||||
## Age 40 years | 0.00170 (0.00399) | ||||
## Age 41 years | −0.00158 (0.00404) | ||||
## Age 42 years | 0.00222 (0.00413) | ||||
## Age 43 years | −0.000159 (0.00410) | ||||
## Age 44–44.5 years | 0.000781 (0.00558) | ||||
−0.000717 (0.00667) | |||||
No. of unemployment spells | 104,437 | 281,701 | 104,437 | 89,291 | 104,437 |
No. of observations | 602,916 | 1,686,890 | 602,916 | 516,196 | 753,119 |
0.032 | 0.033 | 0.032 | 0.032 | 0.013 | |
Post-reform parallel trend test ( | 0.59 | 0.93 | 0.75 | 0.63 | 0.20 |
Effect on the short-term unemployed ( | 0.84 | – | – | 0.86 | 0.91 |
denote statistical significance at the 1% and 5% levels, respectively.
Other studies evaluating hiring subsidies targeted at the LTU also report positive effects on the job-finding rate. The results cannot be directly compared since the targeted population, the take-up rate, the subsidy amount, and the subsidy duration differ. Sjögren and Vikström (2015) find that a hiring subsidy in Sweden targeted at jobseekers unemployed or out of the labor force for at least 1 year increased the job-finding rate by 5.8%. This was the finding for the case that the payroll tax (31.4%) was no longer due for a period equal to their time in unemployment or out of the labor force, thereby decreasing labor costs on average by 24% during this period. Doubling the subsidy or doubling the duration of the subsidy increased the job-finding rate by 28% and 65%, respectively. Ciani
In order to make the findings of these studies more comparable, we calculate the elasticity of the transition from unemployment to employment with respect to the labor cost. The Belgian hiring subsidy reduced the labor cost by 13% at the median wage level and increased the transition to employment by 13% [95% CI: 5–20%], so that the elasticity equals −1 [95% CI: −1.54 to −0.38]. Similar calculations yield an estimate of this elasticity in Italy of −2.2 and −2.5, respectively, for the studies of Pasquini
At the bottom of Table 2, we report the results of two placebo tests. First, we test whether the job-finding rate evolved in parallel in the treatment and control groups in the post-reform period. This approach corresponds to pretending that the reform took place in a “placebo” year after the reform (e.g., in 2017 rather than in 2016) and testing whether the triple-interaction term is insignificant in this case. As explained earlier, the credibility of our DiD approach requires that the parallel trend in the post-reform period – when both treatment and control groups are not treated – holds. This is the case.
The parallel trend also holds in the pre-reform period, which indicates that the effectiveness of the hiring subsidy is not sensitive to the business cycle. This is noteworthy because recent studies have found that wage and hiring subsidies are more effective during downturns (Benzarti and Harju, 2021) and in regions with higher levels of unemployment (Saez
To rule out bias due to dynamic sorting, we test for autocorrelation based on the Breusch–Godfrey LM test of autocorrelation. To this end, the population is split into groups using all possible combinations of the explanatory variables included in the regression, and the average error in each group is calculated. The grouped error is regressed on the lagged grouped error and the explanatory variables using the inverse of the variance of the dependent variable as weights (Table A7 in Appendix A). We find a small, but significant, positive autocorrelation of 0.053.
In Table 2, we report Huber–White standard errors robust for heteroskedasticity. We could also cluster the standard errors at the individual level to take into account that a minority of the jobseekers have multiple unemployment spells, which could explain the small, positive autocorrelation. In the baseline specification, the clustered standard errors are equal to 0.00361, only slightly larger than the robust standard errors (0.00358).
Finally, we examine whether the results are sensitive to the cutoff date, which determines whether jobseekers are classified in the pre-reform or post-reform period. In the baseline specification, we assume that jobseekers who registered at the PES after June 1, 2016, are not eligible for the hiring subsidy. However, jobseekers who registered at the PES in June 2016 become eligible for the subsidy in December 2016. In practice, these jobseekers do not have much time to obtain the necessary documents proving eligibility. For this reason, we classified these jobseekers in the control group. The results are not sensitive to the choice of the cutoff. The results remain unaltered under the following conditions: (1) using July 1, 2016, as the cutoff date; (2) excluding jobseekers who registered at the PES in June 2016 from the regression; and (3) excluding jobseekers who registered at the PES in the period April–June 2016 (as these jobseekers may not have enough time to apply for the necessary certificates). These sensitivity analyses are presented in Table A6 in Appendix A.
The triple-difference approach exploits differences across unemployment duration, age, and time periods. Substitution and anticipation effects can bias the triple-difference estimates. Regressions 2–4 in Table 2 examine and rule out the possibility that the presence of substitution or anticipation effects bias the findings. This also indicates the absence of general equilibrium effects: the positive effects on the job-finding rate of the target group are not at the expense of ineligible groups.
First, we consider eight age groups to examine whether, prior to the reform, employers hired older jobseekers eligible for the hiring subsidy at the expense of younger jobseekers. Using the triple-difference approach, we evaluate whether the job-finding rates of jobseekers younger than 44.5 years improved after the abolition of the subsidy. To do so, we compare the job-finding rate of jobseekers by age in the age group 38–44 years to the job-finding rate of jobseekers aged 35–37 years. Under the assumption that the substitutability decreases with the age differential, then, if substitution effects do matter, the positive effect of the subsidy on the older eligible unemployed will be at the expense of the job-finding rate of those below the eligibility threshold, and, more so, the closer the age is to the eligibility threshold. For this reason, we also included jobseekers aged 44–44.5 years in the regressions – a group excluded in the baseline specification – because this age group is just below the age eligibility threshold, and, therefore, most likely to be negatively affected by the hiring subsidy. There is no evidence that the job-finding rate of jobseekers just below the eligibility threshold improved after the abolition of the hiring subsidy (Table 2, Regression 2).
Second, we examine whether, prior to the reform, the LTU were hired at the expense of the short-term unemployed. Again, we find no evidence of these substitution effects. The job-finding rate of jobseekers aged 45–48 years and unemployed for 5 months did not improve after the abolition of the subsidy relative to the job-finding rate of jobseekers in the same age group unemployed for <5 months (Table 2, Regression 3).
We also compared the job-finding rate of jobseekers unemployed for 5 months with the job-finding rate of jobseekers unemployed for 1 month, 2 months, 3 months, or 4 months. None of the triple-interaction terms is significant at conventional levels, providing additional evidence that the job-finding rate of jobseekers unemployed for 5 months did not improve after abolition of the subsidy.
Third, we examine anticipation effects. The decision to abolish hiring subsidies for the LTU took time and was not (unexpectedly) announced at a specific point in time. Hence, employers could have anticipated the reform and hired more LTU jobseekers just before the abolition of the subsidy. The reform was, however, barely discussed in the Flemish media
We conducted a search of the Flemish media using GoPress. A few newspaper articles in 2015 mentioned that the existing hiring subsidies would be reformed and suggested that the hiring subsidies for the long-term unemployed might be abolished. In 2016, several newspaper articles discussed the reform in more detail.
While the subsidy increased the job-finding rate of the LTU, the question remains whether the subsidy successfully created stable employment. Descriptive evidence presented earlier indicates that subsidized employment tends to be a short-lived process. Moreover, search and matching models predict that hiring subsidies increase job creation and job destruction, leading to less-stable jobs (Kaas and Kircher, 2015; Mortensen and Pissarides, 2001). Most previous studies have not focused on employment stability, although creating stable jobs is often an explicit objective of hiring subsidies. One notable exception is the study by Sjögren and Vikström (2015), who present evidence that workers holding subsidized jobs are more likely to retain their job even after the subsidy expires. A recent evaluation of a payroll tax cut for young workers in Sweden also finds persistent effects after the workers’ age moves out of eligibility and even after abolition of the policy (Saez
To test the effect of the subsidy on employment stability, we again rely on the triple-difference approach but use different outcome variables. We first use a more stringent definition of “employment”, which excludes temporary help agency work. Next, we define two related outcome variables that capture employment stability. The first outcome is defined as finding a job and remaining employed for 1–12 consecutive months after being hired, while the second outcome is defined as finding a job and being employed for 1–12 (not necessarily consecutive months) in the next 12 months after being hired. The second indicator allows us to test whether short-lived employment spells created by the subsidy serve as a stepping stone to other (short-lived) employment spells within the next 12 months.
As mentioned earlier, the Flemish PES records different types of “work”. The regressions presented so far consider any type of employment as a positive outcome. The fifth regression in Table 2 uses a more stringent definition of work, which excludes several types of atypical work, most importantly, temporary help agency work that lasted between 10 days and 20 days per month. Excluding atypical work as a positive outcome halves the triple-interaction term to −0.6 pp, but the effect remains statistically significant at the 5% level. This is a first indication that the hiring subsidy mainly created short-lived employment and had a more-limited effect on the creation of more-stable employment.
To further examine employment stability, we redefine the outcome as finding a job and remaining employed for several (consecutive) months in the next 12 months after being hired, again including all types of work. Figure 4 visualizes the results of the triple-difference regressions for both outcomes. The subsidy has a more pronounced effect on finding short-lived employment than on longer-lasting employment. The effect of the abolition of the subsidy converges toward zero with increasing employment duration. While the abolition of the subsidy reduced the likelihood of being employed for at least 1 month by 1.18 pp, the abolition reduced the likelihood of being employed for at least 6 and 12 consecutive months by 0.41 and 0.05 pp, respectively. In relative terms, this implies that the hiring subsidy increased the job-finding rate by 13%, but it only increased the probability of being employed for at least 6 and 12 consecutive months by 6.6% and 1.5%, respectively. This is in line with the graphical evidence presented in Figure 2, which suggests that the employment trajectories of individuals hired with a subsidy were less stable than those of individuals hired without a subsidy.
Figure 4
The effect of abolition of the subsidy on the probability of finding employment lasting 1–12 (consecutive) months.

Abolition of the subsidy has only a slightly larger effect on the number of months worked (not necessarily consecutive) over a 12-month period after being hired (Figure 4, right panel) than on the number of consecutive months worked over the same period (Figure 4, left panel). Hence, the short-lived employment spells created by the subsidy do not serve as stepping stones to other employment spells in the next 12 months.
The results remain qualitatively similar when using the more stringent definition of employment (Figure A3 in Appendix A). While the subsidy's effects on the job-finding rate are more limited when excluding atypical work, the effect of the subsidy on stable employment still tends toward zero for employment spells that last at least 12 (consecutive) months.
In this section, we examine whether certain groups of jobseekers benefited more from the hiring subsidy. We explore effect heterogeneity along two dimensions: gender and level of education. These dimensions are important for three reasons. First, systematic reviews of ALMPs often report estimates along these dimensions. For instance, the review of Card
Table 3 examines the effect of abolition of the subsidy on the job-finding rate and on employment stability by gender and level of education. The hiring subsidy is more effective for jobseekers with at least a bachelor's degree. It also appears to be more effective for women (+21.4% in relative terms) than men (+7.8%), but the difference between the effects on men and women is not statistically significant (Table 3, Column 1).
The post-reform placebo tests also hold for each of the subsamples. This observation rules out the possibility that the effect heterogeneity observed here can be attributed to a failure of the parallel trend for specific groups. We grouped jobseekers with low and medium levels of education because we did not observe differences between these groups.
The effect of the subsidy by gender and level of education
Men | −0.0076 (0.0118) | −0.0048 (0.0039) | −0.0044 (0.0039) |
Women | −0.0168*** (0.0052) | −0.0083** (0.0038) | −0.0041 (0.0042) |
Less than a bachelor's degree | −0.0074*, a (0.004) | −0.0051* (0.003) | −0.0005a (0.0032) |
At least a bachelor's degree | −0.0264***, a (0.0077) | −0.0113* (0.0062) | −0.0163**, a (0.0064) |
denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
The letter “a” indicates statically significant differences between estimates within the same column under the same heading at the 5% level. For instance, in the first column, the effect on jobseekers without a bachelor's degree is significantly different from the effect on jobseekers with at least a bachelor's degree. The job-finding rate among men, women, and jobseekers without and with a bachelor's degree aged 45–48 years who registered at the public employment service in 2017 and are unemployed for 6 months is, respectively, 10.3%, 7.9%, 9.3%, and 8.9%. This information is used to compute the effect of the reform in relative terms.
For all groups, the effect of the subsidy decreases with employment duration, confirming that the subsidy did not create stable employment (Table 3, Column 3). For the higher educated, the effect is still significantly positive for remaining employed for 6 consecutive months, but it is only 60% of its effect on the job-finding rate, and it further decreases to 35% of this effect (not reported in Table 3) when considering 12 instead of 6 consecutive months. Unfortunately, as the subsidy can last as long as 21 quarters, the data do not allow to check whether the effect for the higher-educated group converges to zero after the subsidy expires, but the pattern of the effect does suggest this.
Our findings are the opposite of those of Sjögren and Vikström (2015), who report larger effects for individuals without a university education and also for men. They interpret these findings as suggestive evidence that the private sector, which tends to employ more men, is more responsive to the policy, and that labor demand is more sensitive at the lower end of the pay distribution, which explains why the hiring subsidy is more beneficial to lower-educated workers. The latter explanation is not relevant in our setting because individuals with a bachelor degree hired with the subsidy have only slightly higher wages than individuals without a bachelor degree (mean monthly gross wage of €2,489 vs. €2,139, respectively), presumably as a consequence of the relatively high minimum wages in Belgium [see, e.g., Rycx and Kampelmann (2013)], and that dismissed workers among the high educated are more negatively selected than among the low educated.
We see the following explanations for our findings. First, our analysis focuses on laid-off “mid-career” individuals. At this stage of the career, job loss usually goes in pair with substantial losses in firm-specific labor market experience and human capital. Consequently, the hiring subsidy and the temporary spells of employment cannot compensate for this loss, making it hard without retraining to materialize an enduring – lasting beyond the subsidization period – labor market reintegration. The finding that higher-educated workers are more likely to be temporarily hired than lower-educated workers owing to the subsidy could be related to their acquisition of more general, transferable skills: this makes them more likely to be hired in different jobs than those from which they were laid-off; the subsidy may compensate for the higher wage costs that are required to make these jobs acceptable or may make up for the productivity gap linked to the reallocation.
Second, we already highlighted that the subsidies were mainly used by temporary help agencies. Out of all hires with a subsidy, roughly 60% were hired by temporary help agencies. It is noteworthy that groups that traditionally rely more on the services of temporary help agencies, namely, (men and) lower-educated jobseekers, are also the groups that benefited less from the subsidy. The subsidies seem to have provided a windfall profit for temporary help agencies, which would anyway have offered temporary jobs to low-educated jobseekers. However, without a subsidy, the hiring of jobseekers with a university degree did not seem profitable for these agencies. By the above argument, the wage subsidy could therefore create additional employment for these workers. However, this employment is not long-lasting or does not seem to be a stepping stone to other, more persistent employment, probably because temporary work is not skill enhancing and may even stigmatize workers (Autor and Houseman, 2010; Givord and Wilner, 2015). This is in line with the findings of Cockx and Van Belle (2019) and Cockx
Using a triple-difference approach, this paper studies the effectiveness of a hiring subsidy targeted at jobseekers older than 45 years of age and unemployed for at least 6 months. The subsidy increases the job-finding rate by 13%. This corresponds to an elasticity of of −1 for the transition from unemployment to employment with respect to the labor cost, which is in-between the estimates from evaluations of hiring subsidies targeted at the LTU in Sweden and Italy.
However, the subsidy mainly created temporary employment and had a more-limited effect on entering stable employment, i.e., employment that lasted several months. The effect of the subsidy gradually decreased with the duration of the employment spell, and the subsidy did not improve the likelihood of finding employment that lasted at least 12 (consecutive) months. Most subsidized employment spells were destroyed after a few quarters, well before the subsidy expired. Moreover, the subsidy was more effective for individuals with at least a bachelor's degree, while jobseekers without a bachelor's degree did not benefit from the subsidy. For these reasons, our study points toward a rather limited potential of hiring subsidies to create (stable) employment for the specific target group of prime-aged jobseekers unemployed for at least 6 months considered in this study. This observation contrasts with the rather favorable evaluations in Italy and Sweden and with ALMP meta-analyses that tend to conclude that hiring subsidies are an effective instrument.
These findings are in line with the hypothesis that the displacement costs of job loss for these mid-career workers are so substantial that a temporary subsidy is insufficient for an enduring reintegration into the labor market. Therefore, the type of policies that can be successful for this target group remains an open question. In view of the involved substantial loss in skills and the specificity of these skills, it seems natural that such policies should involve some education or training to provide these workers with the necessary skills to relocate to a new industry (Jacobsen
Figure 1

Figure 2

Figure 3

Figure 4

Figure A1

Figure A2

Figure A3

The impact of abolition of the hiring subsidy on the job-finding rate: full results of the benchmark specification
Month 2 | −0.0407 |
Month 3 | −0.0841 |
Month 4 | −0.0998 |
Month 5 | −0.109 |
Month 6 | −0.111 |
Month 7 | −0.122 |
Month 8 | −0.129 |
Month 9 | −0.132 |
Month 10 | −0.141 |
Month 11 | −0.141 |
Month 12 | −0.143 |
0.0250 |
|
−0.00487 |
|
0.0101 |
|
−0.0231 |
|
− |
|
2013 | −0.00498 |
2014 | 0.00309 |
2015 | 0.0131 |
2016 | 0.0115 |
2017 | 0.0162 |
2018 | 0.0205 |
Low | −0.00236 |
Medium | 0.00423 |
0.00759 |
|
Limited proficiency | −0.00967 |
Good proficiency | 0.00455 (0.00325) |
Excellent proficiency | 0.00491 (0.00329) |
EU-13 | −0.0196 |
Other | −0.0250 |
0.197 |
|
No. of unemployment spells | 104,437 |
No. of observations | 602,916 |
0.032 |
Placebo tests for the benchmark analysis
2012 | 0.00494 (0.00613) | |
2013 | 0.00441 (0.00534) | |
2014 | −0.000794 (0.00559) | |
2016 Q1–Q2 | 0.00574 (0.00762) | |
2016 Q3–Q4 | − |
|
2017 | − |
|
2018 | − |
|
Less than 5 months | 0.00134 (0.00668) | |
6–12 months | −0.0112 |
|
No. of unemployment spells | 104,437 | 104,437 |
No. of observations | 602,916 | 602,916 |
0.032 | 602,916 | |
Pre-reform parallel trend ( |
0.74 | |
Post-reform parallel trend ( |
0.59 | |
No effect on the short-term unemployed ( |
0.84 |
The effect of the subsidy for different populations
Benchmark specification | −0.0118 |
−0.00408 (0.00286) |
Population: all jobseekers | −0.0101 |
−0.00521 |
Population: all jobseekers who worked 4 months prior to registration + jobseekers whose unemployment history is not known | −0.0110 |
−0.00417 (0.00265) |
The effect of the abolition of the hiring subsidy on finding a job and remaining employed for 1–12 consecutive months (Figure 4, left panel in the main text plots the results)
Effect | −0.0118 |
−0.00934 |
−0.00786 |
−0.00445 (0.00308) | −0.00459 (0.00297) | −0.00408 (0.00286) | −0.00361 (0.00273) | −0.00383 (0.00264) | −0.00347 (0.00256) | −0.00191 (0.00248) | −0.000313 (0.00238) | −0.000546 (0.00230) |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
No. of unemployment spells | 104,437 | 104,437 | 104,158 | 103,949 | 103,699 | 103,444 | 103,157 | 102,837 | 102,726 | 102,601 | 102,430 | 102,280 |
No. of observations | 602,916 | 602,323 | 601,458 | 600,846 | 600,165 | 599,403 | 598,250 | 597,607 | 597,227 | 596,763 | 596,209 | 595,688 |
0.032 | 0.028 | 0.026 | 0.024 | 0.022 | 0.021 | 0.021 | 0.022 | 0.022 | 0.022 | 0.021 | 0.020 | |
Post-reform placebo test ( |
0.58 | 0.73 | 0.81 | 0.62 | 0.84 | 0.88 | 0.64 | 0.96 | 0.93 | 0.78 | 0.32 | 0.37 |
Effect on the short-term unemployed ( |
0.91 | 0.85 | 0.75 | 0.94 | 0.94 | 0.77 | 0.89 | 0.87 | 0.73 | 0.50 | 0.44 | 0.39 |
The Breusch–Godfrey LM test on grouped errors
Lagged grouped error | 0.0526*** (0.0109) |
9,742 | |
R2 | 0.021 |
DiD exploiting differences across unemployment duration among older jobseekers and placebo tests
−0.0352 |
−0.0230 |
||
2012 | 0.00626 (0.00444) | ||
2013 | 0.0162 |
||
2014 | 0.00572 (0.00403) | ||
2016 Q1–Q2 | −0.000136 (0.00548) | ||
2016 Q3–Q4 | |||
2017 | |||
2018 | |||
No. of observations | 283,469 | 283,469 | 319,447 |
0.034 | 0.034 | 0.031 | |
Post-reform parallel trend ( |
The impact of the abolition of the hiring subsidy on the job-finding rate: triple-difference estimates
− |
− |
− |
− |
||
## Age 38 years | 0.00779 |
||||
## Age 39 years | 0.000466 (0.00394) | ||||
## Age 40 years | 0.00170 (0.00399) | ||||
## Age 41 years | −0.00158 (0.00404) | ||||
## Age 42 years | 0.00222 (0.00413) | ||||
## Age 43 years | −0.000159 (0.00410) | ||||
## Age 44–44.5 years | 0.000781 (0.00558) | ||||
−0.000717 (0.00667) | |||||
No. of unemployment spells | 104,437 | 281,701 | 104,437 | 89,291 | 104,437 |
No. of observations | 602,916 | 1,686,890 | 602,916 | 516,196 | 753,119 |
0.032 | 0.033 | 0.032 | 0.032 | 0.013 | |
Post-reform parallel trend test ( |
0.59 | 0.93 | 0.75 | 0.63 | 0.20 |
Effect on the short-term unemployed ( |
0.84 | – | – | 0.86 | 0.91 |
The effect of the subsidy by gender and level of education
Men | −0.0076 (0.0118) | −0.0048 (0.0039) | −0.0044 (0.0039) |
Women | −0.0168 |
−0.0083 |
−0.0041 (0.0042) |
Less than a bachelor's degree | −0.0074 |
−0.0051 |
−0.0005 |
At least a bachelor's degree | −0.0264 |
−0.0113 |
−0.0163 |
DiD exploiting differences across age groups for the long-term unemployed and placebo tests
−0.00138 (0.00245) | 0.0101 |
||
2012 | 0.00769 |
||
2013 | 0.00220 (0.00346) | ||
2014 | 0.00463 (0.00363) | ||
2016 Q1–Q2 | 0.00444 (0.00495) | ||
2016 Q3–Q4 | |||
2017 | |||
2018 | − |
||
No. of observations | 241,611 | 241,611 | 361,305 |
0.005 | 0.005 | 0.020 | |
Post-reform parallel trend ( |
0.34 |
Studies on the effectiveness of private employment programs for the long-term unemployed included in the review by Card et al. (2018) (studies not included in the bibliography)
Active labor market policies in Denmark: A comparative analysis of postprogram effects | Blanche | 2011 | U | Denmark |
Evaluating the impact of a well-targeted wage subsidy using administrative data | Cseres-Gergely, Scharle, Földessy | 2012 | U | Hungary |
The effectiveness of targeted wage subsidies for hard-to-place workers | Jaenichen, Stephan | 2011 | Germany | |
Evaluation of subsidized employment programs for long-term unemployed in Bulgaria | Mihaylov | 2011 | Bulgaria | |
Do long-term unemployed workers benefit from targeted wage subsidies? | Schünemann, Lechner, Wunsch | 2013 | Germany | |
Employment subsidies: A fast lane from unemployment to work? | Forslund, Johansson, Lindquist | 2004 | U | Sweden |
Income support policies for part-time workers: A stepping-stone to regular jobs? | Cockx, Robin, Goebel | 2010 | U | Belgium |
An application to young long-term unemployed women in Belgium | ||||
Dynamic treatment assignment: The consequences for evaluations using observational data | Fredriksson, Johansson | 2008 | U | Sweden |
Van Ours | 2000 | Book | Slovakia | |
The locking-in effect of subsidized jobs | Van Ours | 2004 | Slovakia |
Characteristics of jobseekers by age group and unemployment duration: Age group; Unemployment duration, before and after the reform
41.48 | 41.44 | 41.49 | 41.44 | 46.47 | 46.47 | 46.48 | 46.46 | 47.13 | 0.77 | |
54.12 | 54.77 | 54.76 | 54.10 | 53.80 | 54.84 | 54.83 | 54.13 | 56.84 | 0.43 | |
Low | 38.74 | 37.66 | 40.99 | 39.50 | 42.73 | 39.37 | 44.15 | 41.56 | 43.33 | −1.18 |
Medium | 39.69 | 39.01 | 38.72 | 37.59 | 37.47 | 38.53 | 36.41 | 37.10 | 43.73 | −0.08 |
High | 21.57 | 23.34 | 20.30 | 22.91 | 19.80 | 22.11 | 19.44 | 21.34 | 12.94 | 1.25 |
No | 1.26 | 2.80 | 1.35 | 2.83 | 1.07 | 2.58 | 1.20 | 2.71 | 2.22 | −0.05 |
Limited | 11.22 | 14.17 | 13.25 | 16.06 | 10.06 | 13.08 | 11.79 | 15.48 | 9.61 | −0.81 |
Good | 37.40 | 32.47 | 37.70 | 32.32 | 39.04 | 35.13 | 39.50 | 35.32 | 37.60 | −0.18 |
Excellent | 50.13 | 50.57 | 47.70 | 48.79 | 49.83 | 49.21 | 47.51 | 46.50 | 50.57 | 1.04 |
EU-15 | 74.46 | 68.08 | 70.33 | 63.86 | 80.16 | 73.80 | 76.42 | 70.15 | 77.97 | −0.17 |
EU-13 | 2.16 | 3.46 | 2.44 | 3.58 | 1.76 | 2.97 | 1.95 | 3.35 | 3.11 | −0.34 |
Other | 23.38 | 28.47 | 27.24 | 32.56 | 18.08 | 23.23 | 21.63 | 26.50 | 18.92 | 0.52 |
No. of individuals | 34,318 | 21,127 | 18,259 | 8,332 | 30,405 | 18,587 | 16,381 | 7,192 | 1,221 | – |
The five most important sectors in terms of new hires with a subsidy in each quarter (2015Q2–2016Q4)
Temporary employment agency activities | 61% |
Cleaning activities | 4% |
Restaurants and mobile food service activities | 2% |
Retail sale in nonspecialized stores | 2% |
Other social work activities without accommodation | 2% |
The effect of the subsidy on the job-finding rate: robustness checks
Effect | −0.0125 |
−0.0113 |
−0.0113 |
−0.0116 |
−0.0115 |
|
## Unemployed for 6 months | − |
|||||
## Unemployed for 7 months | − |
|||||
## Unemployed for 8 months | − |
|||||
## Unemployed for 9–12 months | − |
|||||
No. of unemployment spells | 104,437 | 110,930 | 104,437 | 103,322 | 101,296 | 104,437 |
No. of observations | 545,580 | 640,138 | 602,916 | 596,171 | 583,026 | 602,916 |
0.028 | 0.032 | 0.032 | 0.032 | 0.033 | 0.032 |