Uneingeschränkter Zugang

Habit Formation and Preference Change with Capital and Renewable Resources

   | 22. Jan. 2014

Zitieren

1. Abel, A., Bernanke, B.S., Croushore, D. (2007), Macroeconomics, Prentice Hall, New Jersey.Search in Google Scholar

2. Alvarez-Cuadrado, F., Monteriro, G., Turnovsky, S.J. (2004), „Habit formation, catching-up with the joneses, and economic growth“, Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 9, No. 1, pp. 47-80.10.1023/B:JOEG.0000023016.26449.ebSearch in Google Scholar

3. Alvarez-Cuadrado, F., von Long, N. (2011), „Consumption and renewable resource extraction under alternative property-rights regimes“, Resource and Energy Economics, Vol. 33, No.4, pp. 1028-53.10.1016/j.reseneeco.2010.09.003Search in Google Scholar

4. Amato J.D., Laubach, T. (2004), „Implication of habit formation for optimal monetary policy“, Journal of Monetay Economics, Vol. 51, No.2, pp. 305-25.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2003.05.002Search in Google Scholar

5. Ayong Le Kama, A.D. (2001), „Sustainable growth, renewable resources and pollution“, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 25, No. 12, pp. 1911-18.10.1016/S0165-1889(00)00007-5Search in Google Scholar

6. Barbier, E.B. (1999), „Endogenous growth and natural resource scarcity“, Environmental and Resource Economics, Vol. 14, No.1, pp. 51-74.10.1023/A:1008389422019Search in Google Scholar

7. Barro, R.J., Sala-i-Martin, X. (1995) Economic Growth, McGraw-Hill.Search in Google Scholar

8. Becker, G. S. (1992), „Habits, addictions and traditions“, Kyklos, Vol. 45, No. 3, pp. 327-45.10.1111/j.1467-6435.1992.tb02119.xSearch in Google Scholar

9. Becker, G.S., Mulligan, C.B. (1997), „The endogenous determination of time preference“, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112, No. 3, pp. 729-58.10.1162/003355397555334Search in Google Scholar

10. Beltratti, A., Chichilnisky, G., and Heal, G.M. (1994), „Sustainable Growth and the Golden Rule“, in Goldin, I., Winters, I.A. (Eds.) The Economics of Sustainable Development, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.10.3386/w4430Search in Google Scholar

11. Blanchard, O.J., Fischer, S. (1989) Lectures on Macroeconomics, MIT Press.Search in Google Scholar

12. Boldrin, M., Christiano, L., Fisher, J. (2001), „Habit persistence, asset returns, and the business cycle“, American Economic Review, Vol. 91, No.1, pp. 149-66.10.1257/aer.91.1.149Search in Google Scholar

13. Brander, J.A. and Taylor, M.S. (1998), „The simple economics of easter island: A Ricardo- Malthus model of renewable resource use“, American Economic Review, Vol. 81, No. 1, pp. 119-38.Search in Google Scholar

14. Burmeister, E., Dobell, A.R. (1970), Mathematical Theories of Economic Growth, Collier Macmillan Publishers.Search in Google Scholar

15. Cairns, D.R., Tian, H.L. (2010), „Sustained development of a society with a renewable resource“, Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control, Vol. 24, No. 6, pp. 2048-61.10.1016/j.jedc.2010.01.012Search in Google Scholar

16. Campbell, J., Cochrane, J. (1999), „By force of habit: A consumption-based explanation of aggregate stock market behavior“, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 107, No.2, pp. 205-51.10.1086/250059Search in Google Scholar

17. Carroll, C.D. (2000), „Solving consumption models with multiplicative habits“, Economics Letters,Vol. 68, No.1, pp. 67-77.10.1016/S0165-1765(00)00223-8Search in Google Scholar

18. Chang, W.Y., Tsai, H.F., Chang, J.J. (2011), „Endogenous time preference, interest-rate rules, and indeterminacy“, The Japanese Economic Review, Vol. 62, No.2, pp. 348-64.10.1111/j.1468-5876.2011.00540.xSearch in Google Scholar

19. Chao, L.W., Szrek, H., Pereira, N.S., Paul, M. (2009), „Time preference and its relationship with age, health, and survival probability“, Judgment and Decision Making, Vol. 4, No.1, pp. 1-19.10.1017/S1930297500000668Search in Google Scholar

20. Chen, C.H., Lu, Z.N. (2009), „Analysis of the economical growth model with limited renewable resource“, International Journal of Nonlinear Science, Vol. 7, No. 1, pp. 90-4.Search in Google Scholar

21. Clark, C.W. (1976), Mathematical Bioeconomics: The Optimal Management of Renewable Resources, Wiley.Search in Google Scholar

22. Corrado, L., Holly, S. (2011), „Multiplicative habit formation and consumption: A note“, Economics Letters, Vol. 113, No. 2, pp. 116-19.10.1016/j.econlet.2011.06.002Search in Google Scholar

23. Das, M. (2003), „Optimal growth with decreasing marginal impatience“, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 27, No. 10, pp. 1881-98.10.1016/S0165-1889(02)00088-XSearch in Google Scholar

24. Dasgupta, P.S., Heal, G.E. (1979), The Economics of Exhaustible Resources, Cambridge University Press.10.3386/w0436Search in Google Scholar

25. De la Croix, D. (1996), „The dynamics of bequeathed tastes“, Economics Letters, Vol. 51, No.1, pp. 89-96.10.1016/S0165-1765(96)00888-9Search in Google Scholar

26. Deaton, A., Muellbauer, J. (1980) Economics and Consumer Behavior, Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511805653Search in Google Scholar

27. Dioikitopoulos, E.V., Kalyvitis, S. (2010), „Endogenous time preference and public policy: growth and fiscal implications“, Macroeconomic Dynamics, Vol. 14, No. S2, pp. 243-57.10.1017/S1365100510000416Search in Google Scholar

28. Dornbusch, R., Frenkel, J. (1973), „Inflation and growth: Alternative approaches“, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 50, No. 1, pp. 141-56.10.2307/1991068Search in Google Scholar

29. Drugeon, J.P. (1996), „Impatience and long-run growth“, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 20, No. 1-3, pp. 281-313.10.1016/0165-1889(94)00852-3Search in Google Scholar

30. Drugeon, J.P. (2000), „On the roles of impatience in homothetic growth paths“, Economic Theory, Vol. 15, No. 1, pp. 139-61.10.1007/s001990050004Search in Google Scholar

31. Duesenberry, J. (1949), Income, Saving, and the Theory of Consumer Behavior, Harvard University Press.Search in Google Scholar

32. Eliasson, L., Turnovsky, S.J. (2004), „Renewable resources in an endogenously growing economy: Balanced growth and transitional dynamics“, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, Vol. 48, No. 3, pp. 1018-49.10.1016/j.jeem.2003.12.004Search in Google Scholar

33. Epstein, L.G. (1987), „A simple dynamic general equilibrium model“, Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 41, No. 1, pp. 68-95.10.1016/0022-0531(87)90006-8Search in Google Scholar

34. Fuchs, V.R. (1982), „Time PREFERENCE AND Health: An Exploratory Study“, in Fuchs, V.R. (Ed.) Economic Aspects of Health, University of Chicago Press, Chicago.Search in Google Scholar

35. Gómez M.A. (2008), „Convergence speed in the AK endogenous growth model with habit formation“, Economics Letter, Vol. 100, No.1, pp. 16-21.10.1016/j.econlet.2007.10.022Search in Google Scholar

36. Gordon, H.S. (1954), „The economic theory of a common property resource: The fishery“, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 62, No. 2, pp. 124-42.10.1086/257497Search in Google Scholar

37. Gylfason, T., Herbertsson, T., Zoega, G. (1999), „A mixed blessing: Natural resources and economic growth“, Macroeconomic Dynamics, Vol. 3, No. 2, pp. 204-25.10.1017/S1365100599011049Search in Google Scholar

38. Hannesson, R. (2000), „Renewable resources and the gains from trade“, Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 33, No. 1, pp. 122-32.10.1111/0008-4085.00008Search in Google Scholar

39. Hirose, K.I., Ikeda, S. (2008), „On decreasing marginal impatience“, Japanese Economic Review,Vol. 59, No. 3, pp. 259-74.10.1111/j.1468-5876.2008.00406.xSearch in Google Scholar

40. Horioka, C. (1990), „Why is Japan’s households saving so high? A literature survey“, Journal of the Japanese and International Economics, Vol. 4, No. 1, pp. 49-92.10.1016/0889-1583(90)90012-USearch in Google Scholar

41. Huang, M.M. (2012), „Housing deep-habit model: Mutual implications of macroeconomics and asset pricing“, Economics Letters, Vol. 116, No.6, pp. 526-30.10.1016/j.econlet.2012.04.073Search in Google Scholar

42. Jinji, N. (2006), „International trade and terrestrial open-access renewable resources in a small open economy“, Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 39, No. 3, pp. 790-808.10.1111/j.1540-5982.2006.00370.xSearch in Google Scholar

43. Kam, E., Mohsin, M. (2006), „Monetary policy and endogenous time preference“, Journal of Economic Studies,Vol. 33, No. 1, pp. 52-67.10.1108/01443580610639893Search in Google Scholar

44. Kirby, K.N., Godoy, R., Reyes-Garcia, V., Byron, B., Apaza, L., Leonard, W., Perez, B., Vadez, V., Wilkie, D. (2002), „Correlates of delay-discount rates: Evidence from Tsimane Amerindians of the Bolivia rain forest“, Journal of Economic Psychology, Vol. 23, No. 3, pp. 291-316.10.1016/S0167-4870(02)00078-8Search in Google Scholar

45. Lise, L., Seitz, S. (2011), „Consumption inequality and intra-household allocations“, The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 78, No. 1, pp. 328-55.10.1093/restud/rdq003Search in Google Scholar

46. Lucas, R.E. Jr., Stokey, N.L. (1984), „Optimal growth with many consumers“, Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 32, No. 1, pp. 139-71.10.1016/0022-0531(84)90079-6Search in Google Scholar

47. Lusardi, A. (1996), „Permanent income, current income, and consumption: Evidence from two panel data set“, Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, Vol. 14, No. 1, pp. 81-90.Search in Google Scholar

48. Mehra, R., Prescott, E. (1985), „The equity premium: A puzzle“, Journal of Monetary Economics,Vol. 15, No.2, pp. 145-61.10.1016/0304-3932(85)90061-3Search in Google Scholar

49. Meng, Q. (2006), „Impatience and Equilibrium Indeterminacy“, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 30, No. 2, pp. 2671-92.10.1016/j.jedc.2005.07.011Search in Google Scholar

50. Miles, D., Scott, A. (2005), Macroeconomics - Understanding the Wealth of Nations, John Wiley & Sons.Search in Google Scholar

51. Obstfeld, M. (1990), „Intertemporal dependence, impatience, and dynamics“, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 26, No. 1, pp. 45-75.10.1016/0304-3932(90)90031-XSearch in Google Scholar

52. Palivos, T., Wang, P., Zhang, J. (1997), „On the existence of balanced equilibrium“, International Economic Review, Vol. 38, No. 1, pp. 205-24.10.2307/2527415Search in Google Scholar

53. Persson, T., Svensson, L. (1985), „Current account dynamics and the terms of trade: Harberger-Laursen-Metzler two generations later“, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 93, No. 1, pp. 43-65.10.1086/261286Search in Google Scholar

54. Plourde, G.C. (1970), „A simple model of replenishable resource exploitation“, American Economic Review, Vol. 60, No. 3, pp. 518-22.Search in Google Scholar

55. Plourde, G.C. (1971), „Exploitation of common-property replenishable resources“, Western Economic Journal, Vol. 9, No. 3, 256-66.10.1111/j.1465-7295.1971.tb01640.xSearch in Google Scholar

56. Ravn, M., Schmitt-Grohe, S., Uribe, M. (2006), „Deep habits“, Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 73, No. 1, pp. 195-218.10.1111/j.1467-937X.2006.00374.xSearch in Google Scholar

57. Sachs, J.D., Warner, A.M. (2001), „The curse of natural resources“, European Economic Review, Vol. 45, No. 4-6, pp. 827-38.10.1016/S0014-2921(01)00125-8Search in Google Scholar

58. Schaefer, M.B. (1957), „Some considerations of population dynamics and economics in relation to the management of marine fisheries“, Journal of Fisheries Research Board of Canada, Vol. 14, No. 5, 669-81.10.1139/f57-025Search in Google Scholar

59. Sheldon, G. (1998), Fashioning a Culture of Diligence and Thrift: Savings and Frugality Campaigns in Japan, 1990-1931, University of Hawaii Press.Search in Google Scholar

60. Shi, S., Epstein, L.G. (1993), „Habits and time preference“, International Economic Review, Vol. 34, No. 1, pp. 61-84.10.2307/2526950Search in Google Scholar

61. Solow, R. (1956), „A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth“, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 70, No. 1, pp. 65-94.10.2307/1884513Search in Google Scholar

62. Solow, R. (1999), „Neoclassical Growth Theory“, in Taylor, J.B., Woodford, M. (Eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics, North-Holland, Amsterdam.10.1016/S1574-0048(99)01012-5Search in Google Scholar

63. Stern, M.L. (2006), „Endogenous time preference and optimal growth“, Economic Theory, Vol. 29, No. 1, pp. 49-70.10.1007/s00199-005-0019-9Search in Google Scholar

64. Stiglitz, J.E. (1967), „A two sector two class model of economic growth“, Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 34, No. 2, pp. 227-38.10.2307/2296811Search in Google Scholar

65. Storesletten, K., Telmer, C., Yaron, A. (2004), „Consumption and risk sharing over the life cycle“, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 51, No. 3, pp. 609-33.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2003.06.005Search in Google Scholar

66. Uzawa, H. (1968), „Time Preference, the Consumption Function, and Optimum Asset Holdings“, in Wolfe, J.N. (Ed.), Value, Capital and Growth: Papers in Honour of Sir John Hicks, Aldine, Chicago, pp. 485-504.Search in Google Scholar

67. Zhang, W.B. (1993), „A woman’s labor participation and economic growth: creativity, knowledge utilization and family preference“, Economics Letters, Vol. 42, No. 1, pp. 105-10.10.1016/0165-1765(93)90181-BSearch in Google Scholar

68. Zhang, W.B. (2011), „Renewable resources, capital accumulation, and economic growth“, Business Systems Research, Vol. 2, No. 1, pp. 24-35.10.2478/v10305-012-0019-8Search in Google Scholar

69. Zhang, W.B. (2012), „Habits, saving propensity, and economic growth“, Scientific Bulletin - Economic Sciences, Vol. 11, No. 2, pp. 3-15. Search in Google Scholar