Not all jobs are created equal; some are more enjoyable, and some are more highly compensated. Often, the worse jobs also happen to be temporary. Temporary contracts account for the majority, 60%, of new hires in the EU (Arranz et al., 2014) and 14% of the total workforce in 2014 (Eurostat). Many countries apart from Europe, such as Japan and Korea, have seen substantial expansion in temporary contracts making this a truly global phenomenon (e.g. Kawaguchi and Ueno, 2013, Kim and Park, 2006). An increase of such magnitude warrants a closer look at the dynamics of temporary employment because it increases the possibility of an interaction between temporary and permanent employment. Permanent and temporary workers are distinguished by the protection afforded to permanent workers in the form of employer-incurred taxes upon termination. Thus, what happens in a dual labour market if these separation taxes change is of great practical importance
Dual labour markets have coexisting temporary and permanent contracts. This describes many labour markets, but Spain and France are among the most salient examples.
This study develops a model, based on the framework of Diamond, Mortensen, and Pissarides (DMP), to study dual labour markets and derive the implications of an increase in separation taxes. The main novelties of the model are along two dimensions. First, from a theoretical perspective, the model offers an explanation for the coexistence of different contracts and of the associated wage differential in addition to the heterogenous match output. Second, from an empirical perspective, the model predicts the following. Conditional on a decrease in total hires
Increasing separation taxes for newly hired permanent workers has an ambiguous effect on total hires if we do not impose the Hosios condition because it acts as a hiring tax simultaneously, potentially countering the congestion externality inherent in search and matching models. If the congestion externality is either weak or countered by the Hosios condition, an increase in dismissal taxes will decrease employment. In this case, the stated results hold.
France is an example of a dual labour market; since 2000, the share of temporary employees (direct hires and otherwise) has consistently been 10% (13% in 2006, INSEE, Enquete Emploi, 1982 to 2012). France also provides a convenient policy experiment, the ‘Contrat de Transition Professionelle’ (CTP — Professional Transition Contract) enacted in 2006 to test the model's predictions. To finance reemployment assistance, CTP increased separation taxes payable to the government for the ‘licenciement economique’ (separation for economic reasons) of permanent workers hired less than two years ago in firms with fewer than 1,000 workers in seven local labour markets. The empirical analysis exploits the matched French DADS and EAEESANE, BRN datasets along with the CTP policy
The DADS — Déclaration Annuelle des Données Sociale — is administrative data from France that include wages, demographics, and information on the nature of jobs. It covers 85% of France's salaried population. The remaining 15%, composed of the self-employed and state employees, was added in 2009. The EAE-ESANE — Élaboration des Statistiques Annuelles d’Entreprises — and BRN — Bénéfice Réel Normal — contain balance sheet information on private firms. PSM uses the probability of being assigned to the treatment group as a matching criterion for the control group and is the appropriate choice because we have relatively few treated areas and a large number of potential control variables. Due to data restrictions, I cannot follow individuals for longer than one year.
Importantly, the model was not designed to match the above empirical findings which means that it is a prediction of the model that was subsequently supported by the data. Instead, the model was set up to match the following empirical regularities of the French labour market. Temporary contracts exhibit a higher matching rate than permanent contracts. In the early 2000s, 80% of new hires in France were temporary (Cahuc and Postel-Vinay, 2002). The model captures this by having a higher market tightness
This is reminiscent of Berton and Garibaldi (2012), but the workers in this study are heterogenous in their reservation utility allowing for the coexistence of contract types. Here, workers are homogenous and, as we note later, decreasing returns to scale (DRS) are another ingredient that yields coexistence.
Firms employ multiple workers, and wages are determined â la Stole and Zwiebel (1996) whereby temporary workers extract part of the hiring costs, and permanent workers extract the separation taxes on top of the hiring costs, which, for newly hired workers, are lower (more on that below). Permanent contracts (in equilibrium, all hired at the same time) transition to full protection with a fixed probability. This feature is a direct reflection of the French labour market legislation at the time mandating lower firing taxes for permanent workers with less than two years of tenure; precisely what the CTP policy experiment changes.
Departing from Diamond-Mortensen and Pissarides (DMP), the production function exhibits DRS, and TFP is subject to idiosyncratic shocks necessitating adjustments in labour. This assumption allows for multi-worker firms, which, in turn, allows permanent and temporary contracts to coexist in the same firms. In standard DMP-style models with linear technology and homogenous workers, firms are indifferent (hence, they hire both temporary and permanent workers) only at a knife-edge value of the productivity-equating marginal benefit of a temporary and permanent contract. With DRS, this level is endogenously attained. Along with a higher probability of matching applicants to a temporary job, this enables firms to hire workers to such contracts despite an ex post surplus smaller than it is for permanent jobs by equalizing the expected surplus workers obtain from applying.
After a review of the relevant literature, Sections 2 and 3 detail the model. Section 4 explains the identification and data, Section 5 shows the results, and Section 6 concludes.
While the model is inspired by previous work, it differs noticeably from other dual labour market models as it does not require ex ante or ex post heterogeneity or variable match quality to avoid corner solutions (e.g. Berton and Garibaldi, 2012, House and Zhang, 2012, Tejada, 2017). Permanent status is not decided exogenously (Lindbeck and Snower, 2001) but upon vacancy posting, and full protection is automatically granted after reaching a period of tenure. Stable hazard rates for permanent workers challenge some of the more theoretical literature where higher separation taxes make permanent workers even safer (e.g. Alvarez and Veracierto, 2012, Cahuc and Postel-Vinay, 2002,), pointing to the importance of considering the role of temporary workers as buffers. Further, it is supported by the empirical analysis.
At the same time, the model draws upon previous work by Mortensen and Pissarides (1994) as it features a classic matching function. The mechanism that allows the coexistence of different contracts echoes Moen (1997) where a higher ex post surplus is traded for a higher job finding rate. There are multiple workers per firm, much like in Kaas and Kircher (2015) or Acemoglu and Hawkins (2014). Separation taxes are assumed to be exogenous as in Saint-Paul (1998). The wage setting is inspired by Elsby and Michaels (2013), who use the Stole and Zwiebel (1996) approach. Other papers have posited dual labour market set ups. In House and Zhang (2017), different contracts result from adverse selection and hiring costs. Alvarez and Veracierto (2012) grant workers job protection upon reaching a certain tenure. There is also a literature endogenizing dual labour markets via heterogeneous match quality combined with various other frictions; among others, Alonso-Borrego, Fernández-Villaverde, and Galdón-Sánchez (2005), Berton and Garibaldi (2012), Cagesse and Cunãt (2008), Gagesse, Cunãt and Metzger (2019), Cahuc, Charlot, and Malherbet (2016), and Cao, Shao and Silos (2011). The present study, however, features homogenous workers and uses the interplay of multi-worker firms and separation taxes with Stole and Zwiebel bargaining to reproduce key features such as lower wages for temporary workers.
The descriptive empirical literature on temporary workers has strongly influenced modeling choices in this study and includes Segal and Sullivan (1997), Autor (2001), and Houseman (2003a, 2003b). These authors find higher volatility and lower wages for temporary workers (features accounted for in the model) as well as increased usage in recent decades.
The effects of firing costs have been empirically studied at least since Lazear (1990) but this line of inquiry has been hampered chiefly by lack of finely grained and suitably large data. This, coupled with rare availability of natural/policy experiments, means that studies on the effect of firing costs on temporary workers are scarce and there is still some debate on the direction of the effect of firing costs on wages as well as on different groups of workers
This is also the reason why there has been a relatively extensive literature that relies on positing models and calibrating them to gain insight in lieu of empirical analysis. Examples of this include Hopenhayn and Rogerson (1993), who do not distinguish between permanent and temporary workers, and also Alvarez and Veracierto (2012), who do. While these studies tend to find that turnover is reduced as well as general employment, much of this literature is not concerned with dual labor markets and wage effects are highly dependent on the assumptions about wage formation. Ultimately, it is a matter of analyzing real data to confirm, or disconfirm their findings. The CTP increased dismissal taxes only for new hires while, in Italy, dismissal taxes increased for established workers in firms with fewer than 15 workers. This would also mean lower wages for new hires in the present set-up as higher rents at a later stage must be compensated for. Alternatively, the results presented here may be different because of institutions such as stronger unionization in France, and the fact that Italian reforms affected small firms where entrants were less likely to be treated equally. More on equal treatment of new entrants in the model section.
The above means that, while there is some agreement on firing costs lowering turnover, despite vigorous efforts previous evidence is still imperfect as to who benefits or loses exactly, the effect on wages and with regards to the mix of contract types. This study fills some of this gap finding that lower turnover comes in the form of less hiring overall and that existing permanent workers, while insulated from dismissal, are able to extract higher wages. It does so while accounting for the interaction between temporarily and permanently employed workers, and also addressing identification issues by using PSM. The use of this methodology is by no means new and the closest contribution, in terms of methodology, is the study by Gobillon et al. (2012). They used PSM to evaluate the employment effects of the French Enterprise Zones program of 1997, a similarly localized experiment as the CTP, granting wage-tax exemptions to firms hiring locals and finding transitory expansionary effects.
Finally, there has been some previous work on the CTP itself, but more in the form of very preliminary assessments. Remy and Salzberg (2007) provide an early description and an evaluation of the progress of implementation providing recommendations for future measures. A second report, Dole (2010), written by one of the policy designers, contrasts the policy with the conventional reemployment scheme, the CRP (Contrat de Reclassement Personaliseé — Personalized Retraining Contract). The report describes the implementation in more detail and concludes by drawing some practical lessons for future schemes using specific local examples. The report stops short of an econometric analysis, likely due to a lack of readily available data at that time
This is a gap that the present study attempts to address.
Time is discrete and discounted by The results would not change qualitatively were we to postulate state-dependent transition rates (e.g. Foster et al., 2008). This can be justified by arguing that entrepreneurs will only start a business when it is profitable at the beginning and is also a common assumption in the DMP literature, e.g. Pissarides, 2000.
Permanent and temporary workers are perfect substitutes in production, and differences are due to the types of contract, temporary and permanent, both of which are offered in the equilibrium. Permanent contracts have two phases. There is a probationary period that starts at hiring, where dismissal taxes The exact allocation of these transfers is inconsequential because, in equilibrium, they are never paid. Conceptually, it would be relatively straightforward to allow for temporary contracts to be converted to permanent contracts at the end of their duration. However, this would necessitate the introduction of another group of temporary contracts, those that can potentially be converted, which would only exist in recently founded firms. This would necessitate the derivation of another wage schedule and also a taxonomy of multiple cases, some of which would be counterfactual because only new firms would hire temporary workers. While picking out the right sub-case from among these would introduce more realism while retaining the results of the current version of the model, the cost would be a much more cumbersome exposition an already rather complex model and the gain would be limited.
Briefly summarizing, at the beginning of its life, a firm hires permanent workers
Wages are negotiated via Stole and Zwiebel (1996) bargaining, a generalization of Nash Bargaining (Nash, 1953) to a multi-worker set-up. Workers appropriate their own marginal product and the impact their hiring will have on the other workers’ wages through diminishing their marginal product
We make the implicit assumption that negotiation breakdown and a match that dissolves is legally interpreted as dismissal even if the worker decides to ‘walk away’. Workers in France at the time had an incentive not to directly quit but to shift the blame to the employer as they could then collect unemployment benefits (French Labour Code: JORF no214 du 13 Septembre 2002) thus making it a credible threat, particularly if the employer and worker separate in a disagreement over salary.
Figure 1
Timing of the model.

Importantly, new permanent hires are assumed to receive the same wage as incumbents of similar observables (i.e. those still subject to lower firing costs) due to equal treatment contracts (see Snell and Thomas, 2010) or pay-scales (which can even be seen as independent of incumbents). This allows firms to commit to the initial dismissal taxes for permanent positions from the start and to offer separate contracts from temporary ones. Otherwise, firms could negotiate an upfront payment
This does have an empirical basis. Bewley (1999, 2004) furnishes early, survey-based evidence from the United States that firms use pay scales to avoid offering new workers different wages from those of comparable incumbents, controlling for skill and tenure for, moral/social reasons. Montornès and Sauner-Leroy (2015) provide evidence from a 2007 survey among French firms, concluding that pay scales are a major recruiting tool, while potential government enforcement of agreements also seems to play a role. Interestingly, pay scales are thought to be more relevant in highly unionized industries (Bewley, 1999), which is consistent with France's exceptionally high union coverage (98% according to the OECD, despite relatively low union membership). It is tempting to conclude that individual-level bargaining does not have significant influence on wages given such high union coverage. However, in practice, these agreements provide merely a floor, and workers are paid on average 47% above these wages (Fulton, 2015). Thus there is plenty of room for individual bargaining and dismissal costs to play a role. Snell et al. (2017), using German data, uncover evidence that there is no differential dynamic and no ‘catch up’ as workers transition from freshly hired to incumbent (but the data are still rather recent). Dube et al. (2019), using US retail data, find workers are sensitive to equal pay considerations. Saez et al. (2019) find that a payroll tax cut in Sweden for young workers increased wages in affected firms across the board and conjecture that ‘pay equity concerns’ within the firms; that is, (implicit) pay scales or equal treatment contracts, are the cause.
In equilibrium, firms post vacancies of both types until indifferent and workers direct their search; that is, play a mixed strategy trading off a higher ex post surplus for higher ex ante job finding rates (see Moen, 1997). The number of permanent workers retained in the low productivity state delivers zero marginal profits in case of low productivity. Up to the aforementioned level of employment, firms avoid separation taxes and, thus, permanent workers are ex post more profitable. Beyond this point, employers would either incur a loss by paying dismissal taxes on permanent workers or show an operational loss. This serves as justification for why this equilibrium with both types of contracts is likely to prevail and is appropriate for study.
Since we are solving for a steady state, subscripts for the period will be suppressed.
The value,
Where This ensures firms cannot negotiate an upfront payment prior to concluding a permanent contract.
Where the decision variables of the firm are
These value functions are derived assuming permanent workers are never fired unless the firm ceases to exist. We also do not refer to the size of the firm, since there are only two sizes that map one to one to the productivity. The value function for unemployment, Y (after matching happened and, thus, represents the fallback) satisfies:
For these workers, they essentially get their wages and immediately return to unemployment in the next period, reflecting the precariousness of temporary employment.
Wages are determined via the generalization of Nash bargaining by Stole and Zwiebel (1996). Workers and firms negotiate over the marginal surplus of the match and have bargaining weights η for workers and 1 − η for firms. Temporary and permanent workers enjoy the same bargaining weight and only differ in the surplus of the match, permanent jobs being subject to firing taxes f1 for or f2 for the two classes of permanent workers. Additionally, temporary jobs are limited to one period. Solving for wages of temporary and both stages of workers poses some complications since there are three groups of workers influencing each other's wage surplus. To solve, we invoke Lemma 1 which states:
The proof is done by taking the FOC's from the generalized Nash Bargaining a la Stole and Zwiebel and taking the further derivative with respect to the respectively other quantity of workers. We are now equipped to solve for the wages of the workers
Following Cahuc and Wasmer (2001), we assume that the wage bill does not explode as total employment goes to zero, so:
As we can see, just like in a standard search model, wages increase in the bargaining power,
Highly productive firms hire workers until marginal costs equal marginal benefits satisfying:
Here, we must consider the effect of hiring one type of worker on the wages paid to the other two types of workers. Permanent workers confer the benefit of future saved hiring taxes, and temporary workers do not extract firing taxes through wages. Firms need to be indifferent between the two types of hires, thus:
This equation relates market tightness in temporary and permanent labour markets when firms hire both types of worker. Workers too are indifferent. The proportion of permanent workers is determined by how many permanent workers will be profitable in the low-productivity state and will, therefore, be hired during the high productivity phase, implying
The first term is the marginal product, and the second term is the benefit of not having to look for this worker in the future. The remaining terms are the wages for permanent workers in such a firm. The cost of finding the workers is not included since the firm already has the workers and does not need to search. We emphasize that permanent workers are only hired in the first period of a firm's existence and, after that, an ever increasing proportion of them enjoys full protection.
To figure this out, we must first pin down how many workers are initially hired on a permanent contract upon the firm's creation. This is easy as we simply can solve the the first order condition for
We can show the total number of permanent workers that enjoy protection of dismissal costs
The number of workers only enjoying
In what follows, wherever possible we will use the equations
As in the DMP framework, the stock of unemployed evolves according to:
In equilibrium permanent workers are only hired in the first period and then transition to full protection. Recall equation (2.24) for their exact distribution.
This section examines the scenario when
Whether total employment increases or decreases after a rise in
An initial observation is that there is a close connection between the proportion of new permanent workers and the wages that are paid to those workers. If wages increase and total employment goes down, the model makes clear predictions. If, however, the hiring costs decrease sufficiently, there may be cases that are consistent with lower wages as well as lower proportions of permanent workers. In what follows, we outline three cases. To establish the cases, we consider the following two equations that are the derivative of the employment decisions for
These two equations are similar and only differ in as far as the decision on total employment considers the cost of hiring a worker in the first place, whereas the decision on permanent workers considers the situation as to how many of them would be retained. Now, we can state three results covering three cases:
This occurs if both numerators of (3.15) and (3.16) are negative, which is the case when the increase in f1 increases the wages of recently hired permanent workers more than the resulting reduction in vacancy posting reduced the aggregate costs of labour search by alleviating the congestion externality. The denominator of (3.15) is more negative than that of (3.16) due to the positive term
This result is straightforward as it entails that the numerator of (3.15) is negative while that of (3.16) is positive on account of the term
This is the most involved result, and there are two sub-cases involved. The ambiguity arises because if the numerator of (3.15) and (3.16) is positive, that of (3.15) is naturally larger because of the additional positive term
If this inequality holds, we have a decrease in the ratio of permanent to total employment and the reverse if it does not hold. Inspection of the left-hand side and right-hand side of (3.17) reveals that the left-hand side represents a measure of the reaction of wage costs for permanent workers to firing taxes (net of any additional effects and a higher marginal product due to downsizing) while the right-hand side represents the elasticity of the hiring costs. Naturally, if the elasticity of the hiring costs with respect to firing taxes is higher, this implies that the cost of hiring workers is falling faster than the cost of retaining them. This means that the marginal hiring decision is affected more favorably than the retention decision. Once we realize that this wider hiring margin translates to more temporary workers while the retaining margin translates to more permanent workers, it is clear that a greater hiring elasticity with respect to firing taxes translates to a decrease in permanent workers relative to total employment.
One result is that when separation taxes for recent hires
Recently hired permanent workers are not dismissed in the model at this stage as there is no instance in the model where their firm would become less productive when they are still recently hired19
Even if the firm were still in the current period when higher firing taxes were instituted, firms would not fire the permanent workers but would be forced to pay them a higher wage. Naturally, firms will also not hire more permanent workers in such a situation and will actually curtail their hiring. This is because of discounting, the counterbalancing of lower hiring costs and imperfect pass-through of the firing taxes because of bargaining as well as the fact that the increase in f1 is bounded above by f2 − f1. An alert reader may argue that this may also apply to the current set-up if there are more than two states of productivity. This overlooks the fact that if there were multiple productivity states, the number of permanent workers would be determined by the zero profit condition in the least productive state.
In the model, separation taxes do not influence job security for permanent workers because temporary workers absorb the blow. Releasing temporary workers is cheaper. This is a result of firm's motivation to protect core workers from adverse productivity shocks (noted by, e.g. Houseman et al., 2003) to avoid separation taxes and unevenly distributing risk. Further, since temporary workers are only hired for a fixed period and would not assume another contract upon expiration, we expect no measured change in hazard rates of temporary workers.
For identification, this study exploits a policy experiment, the ‘Contrat de Transition Professionelle’, or CTP, that introduced exogenous variation in initial separation taxes among different regions in France. The CTP policy experiment increased separation taxes for economic layoffs of permanent workers hired less than two years ago in firms with fewer than 1,000 workers. These workers were hired up to the same level as workers with more than two years’ tenure. This means, in terms of the model, that Employment zones are ‘areas where most of the working age population resides and works’ (INSEE) The reasons why these were not used are twofold. First, in 2009, the employment zones were reassigned reflecting changing living and working patterns. The focus on 2005 to 2008 means that the Great Recession is less of a concern because it hit France late, in 2009.
Figure 2
Differences between CRP and the CTP scheme.

For eligible workers, there was a slightly higher unemployment benefit if they had tenure with their previous employer of less than two years and a reward from what was left of the allocated funds for finding a job. The data analysis does not find any effect of these aspects24
These aspects are not specifically accounted for in the model. The reason is that the reward for finding a job and the slightly higher unemployment benefit counteracted each other. Thus, adding them to the model would have complicated it vastly without providing additional insight. This choice is justified in the subsequent data analysis, which shows no signs of workers currently eligible for the CTP negotiating any change to wages; only workers that could use the CTP as a threat against employers did so. This seems to indicate that these two aspects of the policy did in fact neutralize each other. It is, unfortunately, not possible to tell with the data at hand if individual workers found jobs faster with the help of the policy, but the overall negative effect on employment makes this unlikely. A perspective might be that the Labour Force Survey/’Enquête d’Emploi’ could rectify this; however, sadly, the survey does not record the location of employers, current or previous (the qualifying criterion for benefitting from the policy), making it impossible to isolate the effect of the policy.
The employment zones assigned to the CTP in 2006 were Toulon, Valenciennes, Charlevilles-Mézièrs, Montbéliard, Saint Dié, Vitré, and Morlaix. The then Minister of Employment, Jean-Louis Borloo, announced the CTP on 12 December 2005 in ‘La Tribune’ (Le Monde, 2005). The CTP came into effect on 15 April 2006. The zones are economically deprived areas with declining heavy industries (shipping, steel production, etc.). For instance, the employment share of services was 71.9% in 2005 as opposed to 78.6% nationwide. Therefore, PSM is used to find a valid comparison group.
Figure 3
Results for Google searches. 100% in July 2009 corresponds to the highest number of searches.

One concern a reader may have is whether this policy was truly a surprise to firms and employees. The following graph provides some evidence:
The first interest on Google appears in December 2005, the month of the announcement, and there is another peak in April 2006 when the policy came into effect. Later peaks correspond to expansions of the CTP into other zones
Other search items such as ‘Flexicurité’, or search items related to the experimentation areas, did not yield any significant changes.
There are two main data sources — the DADS-Postes Fichiers, providing information on workers, and EAE-ESANE, containing balance sheet information on firms. For the analysis of flow and stock numbers of workers, the BRN was matched with DADS. For the propensity score, an auxiliary dataset was used containing publicly available information on unemployment in the employment zones and summary statistics from the main data sources. It is worth remembering that the data in this auxiliary dataset contain the information the policy designers had at their disposal at the time.
The DADS (or ‘Déclaration Anuelle des Données Sociales’, Annual Declaration of Social Insurance Data) contains social insurance data collected for administrative purposes and covers 85% of salaried employees in France each year, except for employees of the central government (ministries), public health workers, and people employed by individual households (cleaners, childcare workers, etc.). Individual identifiers are reassigned each year to ensure anonymity. However, the data include information for the current and previous year, so we can follow individuals over time. Extra-territorial activities are excluded. Variables include salaries, employment duration (during the year), the date of commencement and termination of the match
If either are beyond the timeframe of the dataset, the date is given as the first and last day in the observed period.
The EAE-ESANE (or ‘Elaboration des Statistiques Annuelles d’Entreprises’) datasets provide yearly balance sheet information on a sample of firms that covers approximately 10% of firms (agriculture and heavy industry are covered completely). The variables include net revenue, number of employees on 31 December, nature of principal activity, geographical area of activity (down to commune level), net assets, investment, and so on. The BRN (‘Bénéfice Régime Réel Normaux’) dataset contains balance sheet information as well and covers roughly 80% of total sales in the economy, which it achieves by covering firms beyond e 763k in revenue (e230k for services). Since both the EAE-ESANE and the BRN datasets are samples (albeit large ones), their representativeness is difficult to ascertain.
PSM is used at the employment zone level to identify a group of control areas using nearest-neighbor matching with replacement. First, we look at overall trends in permanent and temporary employment and, subsequently, we conduct PSM-adjusted regressions to examine the effect of the policy on hourly wages and employment hazard rates out of employment. To estimate the effect of the CTP on the seven employment zones, we could use OLS. However, we would have to search for many controls, and several observations would simply not be comparable to those affected
Regression discontinuity is also not suitable, first, due to general equilibrium effects as affected firms employ most workers. Second, and perhaps more critically, the threshold of 1,000 employees is an important determinant of more demanding employment protection legislation and other legal requirements firms must fulfill, and firms are naturally able to perfectly sort into size categories as has been explored by Garicano et al. (2016). This provides ample reason to believe that firms that find it worthwhile to hire more than 1,000 workers differ systematically from those that do not, which violates the as-if-random assumption necessary for regression discontinuity design (e.g. Lee and Lemieux, 2010). For instance, since 2002, firms with more than 1,000 employees had to provide the ‘congé de reclassement’, a reemployment programme even more stringent than the CTP (Code de Travail L. 321-4-3 and 321-10 to 321-16, all passed in 2002).
Clearly, CTP zones (column 1) are not representative of France (column 3). The share of permanent workers is higher, manufacturing is overrepresented, and services are underrepresented. Unemployment is higher as is the proportion of unqualified workers. The average wage is lower by a euro, but income per employment stint is higher. This can be explained by the higher proportion of permanent workers. Finally, the proportion of locals with local jobs is higher, indicating low mobility. The control zones (column 2) chosen by propensity scores are similar to the treatment zones. The share of permanent workers is closer by 1% and the share of manufacturing by 0.4%. The service sector share is not closer, indicating it was not important in determining the probability of assignment, which is surprising. Unemployment is higher in the control group, indicating some overshooting. The match is better for hourly wages, income, proportion of non-residents, and the proportion of residents with local jobs, a measure of isolation. This indicates that wages, income, and the degree of isolation were the most important characteristics of these struggling regions in determining the application of the CTP. Additionally, policy makers seem keenly aware that in addition to income, the degree of influx from other regions is an important sign of economic well-being. After all, influx shows that the area is attracting outsiders by offering opportunity. Finally, it is worth noting that the average control zone is approximately one third in size relative to the average CTP (treatment) zone. This can be seen in the number of employed workers at the end of 2005: 62,619 on average in the CTP and 37,069 in control zones.
CTP versus control zones, pre-policy characteristics
Stock of Permanent Workers | 67.1% (4.64) | 66.9% (1.39) | 65.1% (5.87) |
Manufacturing Share | 20.8% (11.2) | 20.0% (11.5) | 19.6% (9.1) |
Services Share | 71.9% (11.35) | 79.0% (11.5) | 78.1% (9.6) |
Unemployment | 9.3% (5.4) | 10.4% (4.5) | 8.0% (6.3) |
Change in Unemployment since 04 | −0.66% (0.544) | −0.04% (0.35) | −0.30% (6.3) |
Permanent Share Predicted by Productivity Proxy | 57.2% (1.7) | 57.4% (1.2) | 57.0% (2.6) |
Participation Rate | 70.7% (4.7) | 70.6% (4.4) | 71.4% (2.8) |
Proportion of Unqualified Workers | 17.7% (4.38) | 14.8% (3.8) | 14.6% (3.9) |
Average Age of Workers | 39.2 (0.7) | 38.6 (0.3) | 39.5 (0.8) |
Average hourly Wages in 05 (Euro) | 14.22 (0.81) | 14.01 (0.73) | 14.55 (2.78) |
Average Gross Income in 05 (Euro) | 14258.76 (1207) | 14023.09 (743) | 13732 (1976) |
Non-Residents in Workforce | 48.8% (18.0) | 52.6% (8.95) | 70.5% (27.2) |
Locals with Local Job | 79.5% (9.6) | 78.1% (4.65) | 67.8% (19.6) |
Variables refer to the value in December of 2005.
Standard Errors in parentheses.
Recently, there have been contributions such as King and Nielsen (2019) that caution against the naive use of PSM. Their main argument is that as the Propensity score is merely a summary of the determinants of the probability, it is entirely possible that a similar score may be hiding a very dissimilar combination of determinant factors. The focus of the method on the nearest match of this score may lead to the selection of observations that have a similar score because of a combination of factors that randomly matches the combined score, King and Nielsen (2019) refer to this as excessive “pruning”. This produces the danger that the control group is more different from the treatment group than the general population. To address this, King and Nielsen (2019) suggest to, at least, provide the reader with a measure of the presence and severity of the problem and calculate measures of distance of the individual members of the treatment group to the general population average and to the matched control. Since there is no generally agreed upon measure of distance in this context, the table below shows various measures from Euclidean distance, over Correlation to Chebychev distance and Shape Distance. It will reassure the reader that every single measure shows that PSM has yielded a control group that is more similar to the treatment group.
Various Distance Measures of CTP zones in comparison to France and the Control Group
Euclidian Distance | 34.75 | 31.87 |
Size Distance | 10.67 | 9.13 |
Correlation | 0.95 | 0.96 |
Correlation Transformed to Euclidian Distance | 0.2 | 0.18 |
Squared Correlation | 0.91 | 0.93 |
Chebychev Distance | 25.19 | 22.24 |
Manhattan Distance | 23.46 | 19.13 |
Shape Distance Component 1 | 3.13E-15 | 4.34E-15 |
Shape Distance Component 2 | 32.98 | 30.15 |
Shape Distance Component 3 | 3.29E-15 | 3.22E-15 |
To ensure consistency, nominal variables have been normalized.
While the distance measures are not 0 and the correlation measures are not 1 for the control groups, there seems to be some marked improvement relative to the rest of France across the board. This indicates that PSM has in fact not selected a control group that is only superficially, i.e. in the assignment probability, similar to the treatment group. While the overall distance of traits of the control group is closer to the treatment group, the probability of assignment is closer as well, which means we have improved the comparability of treatment and control without incurring a high cost of imbalance of traits. Equipped with some degree of confidence in the matching methodology, we can now turn to describing the empirical results.
Now, we proceed to test the predictions using the CTP policy experiment. To summarize, permanent workers are buggered from shocks, and the model has predictions concerning the impact of an increase in the firing tax; relevantly, in the case of less economic activity, fewer permanent workers, higher wages, and stable hazard rates for permanent workers
If economic activity declines, wages for temporary workers increase.
Figure 4 shows average inflows of workers in treatment and control areas normalized by their values in December 2005, when the policy was announced. The figure shows 2,172 incoming workers in the CTP and 1,265 incoming workers in the control areas, on average. This reflects that the average control area is approximately 30% smaller than the average treatment area but, otherwise, quite similar. In fact, we see little difference in the employment trajectory before the policy is implemented (April 2006). This confirms the groups’ share trends, indicating the propensity score was successful in identifying control zones sufficiently similar to the treatment zones. Additionally, there also is no clear trend in general employment flows in the treatment zones after the policy announcement, which is disappointing, but the model is ambiguous concerning the general employment effect. There is a seasonal pattern; substantial hiring occurs in January and in July. We see a smaller spike each year, however, this may be due to the impending Great Recession. Looking at the stock of workers (Figure 5), employment declined relative to control areas after the announcement, although not statistically significantly. This (weakly) indicates reduced economic activity due to more expensive workers, which is one possibility outlined by result 1 in the model when the increased firing taxes are too large and go beyond correcting for high incentives that encourage firms to hire workers. The increased help for workers seeking jobs is not efficient. However, disentangling the positive effects of the improved job-seeking assistance and the negative effects of the firing taxes would necessitate information on the job finding rates of the unemployed, which, unfortunately, we do not have since the data only cover the employed.
Figure 4
The total flows have been normalized to their values of December 2005, the time the policy was announced: 2,172 on average in CTP areas and 1265 in control areas. The dashed lines represent (bootstrapped) confidence intervals.

Figure 5
The total stocks have been normalized to their values for December 2005: 62,619 workers on average in the CTP zones and 37,069 in the control zones. The dashed lines represent (bootstrapped) confidence intervals.

The model predicts fewer permanent workers (results 1 and 2). This section provides evidence that supports this. For flows of permanent workers, the groups share the same trend; that is, fewer permanent workers are hired. There is a spike of 9% in permanent employment in the control areas in August 2006, after the implementation of the policy, that is not shared by CTP areas, although they share the same trend and hire in similar numbers. Such an event seems missing in 2007, but in September 2008, we observe a relative rise in permanent hires in the control group. Note that the significance levels of the difference between the treatment and control groups for flows29
Available upon request. The appendix shows that durations for permanent workers decreased.
The control group has a higher proportion of permanent workers than CTP areas of between two and 10 percentage points, starting in January 2006, after the policy was reported in Le Monde (12 December 2005). This means that firms immediately adjusted their stock of permanent workers as a response to the policy. The beginning of the year is typically a time of higher permanent work contract flows, as can be seen in the seasonal pattern in Figure 4, which may have been a factor. It is further noticeable that the confidence intervals cease, including for the other group, at the time of the policy announcement. Figure 8 shows the statistical significance of the difference between the ratios of permanent workers of the treatment and control areas. The difference is not significant before the policy at any conventional significance level and, precisely when the policy is announced, the ratio in treatment areas drops and becomes statistically significantly different at the 10% level (and higher) for most months. This is evidence in favor of the model (but not exclusive to it). Results 1 and 2 predict fewer permanent workers as a response to increased initial firing taxes along with less employment. An important question is: What was the margin of adjustment? From the graphs, in particular figure 5, we see that employment always dips between November and December of any given year. This applies to temporary jobs and permanent jobs. The ratio of permanent jobs increases rather strongly at the beginning of each year, only to peter out throughout the year and regain ground once again at the beginning of the next year. The end of the year is a time when many jobs, permanent and temporary, are terminated. However, relatively more temporary jobs are dissolved automatically increasing the proportion of permanent jobs. Incidentally, the policy was announced at exactly that time (December 2005), so the firms could adjust immediately.
Figure 6
The dashed line shows the 10% (bootstrapped) confidence intervals around the ratios depicted in the same color.

Figure 7
The dashed line shows the 10% (bootstrapped) confidence intervals around the ratios depicted in the same color.

Figure 8
The dashed lines show the 10% (bootstrapped) confidence intervals and the 5% confidence interval.

The reader may wonder, why the proportion of the stock of permanent workers in the treatment zones is falling so much relatively to the control zones in November/December of each year as we can see in figure 7. This is due to the overall reduction in hiring that we can observe in figure 5 as well as a shift of employers to use temporary workers more extensively and employ them for slightly longer (but still temporary) time horizons in response to the changed regime. This may be especially pronounced in the final months of the fiscal and budgetary year because decision makers may not have fully internalized their lower “budget” of permanent vacancies yet since the CTP was novel, but the exact dynamics are beyond the scope of this study.
We are tempted to construct graphs for all subsets of firms, but this may be misleading since there are general equilibrium effects between firms with less than and more than 1,000 workers, and in such graphs it is not possible to control for confounding factors. The aggregate of the treatment and control zones is informative since the propensity score balances potential confounding factors. This is why we move on to propensity score adjusted regressions.
Now, we examine hourly wages, hazard rates out of employment, hours worked, and income by conducting PSM-adjusted regressions at the match (employment stint) level. Higher wages occur with firing taxes in other models also (e.g. Garibaldi and Violante, 2005), but they still support the model when coupled with the above results of fewer permanent workers and lower employment overall, consistent with result 1. In fact, only higher wages are consistent with lower employment in the model. We conduct propensity score adjusted difference-in-difference regressions (interacting variables if the match was in an affected zone) on the sample of treated and control employment zones. The unit of observation is the match between worker and firm. Constant hazard rates (i.e. later match formation) constitute evidence in favor of the model. In the model, permanent workers are only fired in particularly hard times regardless of the level of f. This means that firms reduce their use of labour, not through higher hazard rates for permanent workers, but through less hiring.
For wages the regression specifications are:
The a's are intercepts. Unreported controls in the first specification also include: age, age squared, blue or white-collar jobs, sex, a proxy for firm productivity, if the job was in manufacturing or services, if it was a permanent job, year controls, if the worker is a resident, and interactions of year and permanent indicators. I do not report the results on indicators individually, such as being in an affected zone, being a permanent worker, due to space concerns and because they do not reveal anything of interest. The second specification adds indicators of firm size, if it was a new firm, and various interaction terms. The third specification adds controls if the workers held permanent jobs before in the control group and if workers were eligible. The third specification interacts the indicators with year dummies. The fourth specification via X7 adds combinations of controls for having held a permanent job before, being eligible for the policy while holding a permanent job now, and being in the control group.
Table 2 reports the results for regressions with the log of hourly wage as a dependent variable. Flows are workers newly hired in that year while stocks denote incumbents.
Impact on hourly Wages
CTP zone (post 15.4.2006) | 0.003 (0.01) | 0.056 (0.036) | −0.014 (0.026) | 0.015 (0.033) | −0.015 (0.021) | 0.014 (0.032) | −0.014 (0.027) | 0.015 (0.025) |
CTP × permanent job | −0.039 (0.03) | 0.074* (0.042) | 0.008 (0.043) | −0.048 (0.04) | 0.004 (0.040) | −0.049 (0.038) | 0.0004 (0.043) | −0.05 (0.035) |
CTP × firm below 1000 | 0.03 (0.028) | 0.006 (0.022) | 0.031 (0.022) | 0.006 (0.022) | 0.03 (0.026) | 0.006 (0.018) | ||
CTP × firm below 1000 × permanent job | −0.067* (0.039) | 0.013 (0.029) | −0.065* (0.036) | 0.013 (0.024) | −0.064* (0.037) | 0.013 (0.032) | ||
CTP × previously held permanent job | 0.0279* (0.0144) | 0.059*** (0.022) | 0.012 (0.014) | 0.0026 (0.031) | ||||
CTP × previously held permanent job × holds permanent job | 0.04* (0.023) | 0.075*** (0.029) | ||||||
CTP × previously held permanent job in CTP × permanent job | −0.164 (0.123) | −0.132 (0.081) | ||||||
average sample size (per pair) | 113938 | 162996 | 113938 | 162996 | 113938 | 162996 | 113938 | 162996 |
0.41 | 0.49 | 0.42 | 0.49 | 0.42 | 0.49 | 0.42 | 0.50 |
The first column shows that for newly hired workers, there is no significant effect in the first (most naive) specification. However, in the second column for the stock of workers, we see that the workers who found a permanent job were able to negotiate a 7.4% higher wage (albeit only significant at 10%). This is in line with the model's prediction that permanent workers negotiate a higher salary as separation taxes increase. The second specification in the third column shows that newly hired workers in firms with less than 1,000 workers obtain a lower wage (only significant at 10%), which is surprising, but reassuringly the finding does not hold once we add further controls. There is no significant estimate for newly hired or retained workers.
The third specification explores the situation among newly hired workers. In the fifth column, it seems (significant at 10%) that permanent workers hired in firms with fewer than 1,000 workers obtain a 6.4% lower wage, which is mitigated by workers who held a permanent job before having a 2.8% higher wage. It appears that new hires are willing to take a lower wage initially to gain a permanent position but leverage the CTP. Considering the average from the first specification does not expose a clear trend; the effects seem to cancel out. However, the sixth column reveals that workers who held a permanent position previously and are now working in a CTP region will increase their wages by 5.9% in the long run (i.e. in the stock of workers), significant at 1%. This is in line with workers extracting more surplus.
Moving to the fourth specification in columns 7 and 8 that includes controls for workers eligible for the policy, we see that it is not workers eligible for the CTP who are negotiating higher wages. It is those workers who have better adherence to the labour force as they had permanent jobs in the last 12 months. Thus, these workers were eligible for the policy. The wage increases by 4% for newly hired workers and 7.5% for the stock of workers32
Firms with fewer than 1,000 workers were not significantly affected, which shows a general equilibrium effect. The Labour Force Survey did not provide indication of whether workers were eligible.
In summary, there is a wage increase for permanent workers, supporting the theory as these are workers whose initial firing taxes were changed, which, with a lower ratio of permanent workers is consistent with results 1 and 2. The treatment effect for temporary workers is positive but insignificant. One caveat is that better workers may have been hired in permanent positions, inflating estimates. This cannot be tested as we cannot follow workers over the years.
The next piece of evidence is if the hazard rates do not change with dismissal taxes. Other models (e.g. Alvarez and Veracierto, 2012) predict that hazard rates decrease for permanent workers. However, in our model, permanent workers already enjoy the most stable employment relationship possible. The following proportional hazard models are fitted:
Table 3 reports the hazard rate estimates using a proportional hazard Cox model. Except for permanent workers newly hired in firms with fewer than 1,000 workers and who are less likely to be fired (only in the second specification, column 3, and only significant at the 10%-level, which makes sense as they are now more expensive to fire), no estimates in the first three specifications are significant. Importantly, there is no significant effect on the stock of workers with any contract. This makes sense in the context of the model as the firing tax prevents firms from firing permanent workers as a response to higher separation taxes. Temporary workers to whom the firing taxes do not apply will be fired at the same rate as before (particularly since temporary workers are hired for fixed terms). Since workers lose their jobs at the same occasions, we should not expect any change in the hazard rates.
Hazard Rates
CTP zone (post 15.4.2006) | −0.100 (0.142) | 0.018 (0.091) | 0.011 (0.243) | 0.218 (0.316) | 0.0148 (0.24) | 0.243 (0.252) | 0.007 (0.218) | 0.236 (0.272) |
CTP × permanent job | 0.142 (0.184) | −0.037 (0.087) | 0.039 (0.326) | −0.179 (0.251) | 0.063 (0.354) | −0.183 (0.249) | 0.073 (0.276) | −0.176 (0.218) |
CTP × firm below 1000 | −0.168 (0.212) | −0.162 (0.338) | −0.172 (0.212) | −0.171 (0.255) | −0.172 (0.199) | −0.16 (0.295) | ||
CTP × firm below 1000 × permanent job | −0.433* (0.223) | 0.159 (0.255) | 0.142 (0.218) | 0.166 (0.232) | 0.144 (0.193) | 0.155 (0.203) | ||
CTP × previously held permanent job | −0.096 (0.108) | −0.157 (0.187) | –0.084 (0.113) | –0.138 (0.204) | ||||
CTP × previously held permanent job × holds permanent job | −1.496* *(0.7) | 0.535 (1.6) | ||||||
CTP × previously held permanent job in CTP × holds permanent job | 1.201* (0.705) | −0.442 (1.567) | ||||||
average sample size (per pair) | 114187 | 163508 | 114187 | 163508 | 114187 | 163508 | 114187 | 163508 |
0.106 | 0.069 | 0.126 | 0.087 | 0.132 | 0.108 | 0.132 | 0.109 |
The fourth specification has some significant estimates. Column 7 shows that eligible workers with a permanent job in a CTP region now have a lower hazard rate (down to 0.2 of the baseline), significant at 5%, and eligible workers who obtained a permanent job have a hazard rate increased by the factor 3 although this is only significant at 10%. This may reflect the structure of the differences between CTP and CRP. Firms may hire permanent workers under the CRP with no intention of letting them stay on after two years. Under the CTP, this is not possible. This does not overturn the conclusion of separation taxes being inconsequential for hazard rates of permanent workers, as we can see in columns 1 to 6 and column 8. Additionally, because it is only recent hires and not workers subject to higher separation taxes in general, this is a composition effect. Finally, hazard rates of the stock of workers is unaffected. In summary, hazard rates are stable as result 4 suggests
In the appendix, duration is explored. We find that workers were hired later, meaning their hazard rates did not change, but utilization decreased.
For firms not hiring new workers (permanent or temporary), a reduction in economic activity, beyond hiring fewer workers, may be reflected by fewer hours worked by those already hired. For hours worked and income, respectively, this was the set of regressions:
Table 4 reports the results on hours worked and total income. The covariates are the same as previously for the fourth specification. However, now several indicators from X7 are reported: if a worker previously held a permanent job in a CTP area and holds any type of job in a CTP area currently, if a worker employed either in a CTP or control area formerly held a permanent job in a CTP area and held a current job in a CTP area, if a worker previously held a permanent job while currently holding a permanent job in a CTP area, if a worker holds a permanent job in a CTP area currently and previously held a permanent job in a CTP area and, finally, if a worker previously held a permanent job in a CTP area and is currently holding a permanent job but not necessarily in a CTP area. There seems to be a redistribution of hours worked from newly hired temporary workers towards permanent workers in new firms only, which reflects fewer overall hires, but permanent workers are used more. In column 1, workers benefitting from the policy directly work more hours in CTP but less (approximately 50%) in other regions. Eligible permanent workers in a CTP region worked less.
Hours worked and total income
CTP zone (post 15.4.2006) | 0.043 (0.088) | 0.070 (0.074) | 0.031 (0.071) | 0.154 (0.099) |
CTP × permanent job | −0.092 (0.084) | −0.042 (0.107) | −0.087 (0.108) | −0.156 (0.184) |
CTP × new firm | −0.432** (0.241) | −0.116 (0.426) | −0.469** (0.233) | −0.169 (0.399) |
CTP × firm below 1000 | −0.016 (0.132) | −0.02 (0.085) | 0.014 (0.128) | −0.093 (0.077) |
CTP × firm below 1000 × permanent job | 0.063 (0.147) | −0.018 (0.119) | −0.003 (0.144) | 0.072 (0.137) |
CTP × new firm × permanent job | 0.636*** (0.269) | 0.045 (0.337) | 0.591** (0.281) | 0.176 (0.296) |
CTP × previously held permanent job in CTP | 0.509* (0.349) | −0.018 (0.386) | 0.537* (0.387) | 0.011 (0.385) |
Previously held permanent job in CTP | −0.502* (0.358) | 0.178 (0.386) | −0.557 (0.401) | 0.176 (0.389) |
CTP × previously held permanent job × holds permanent job | 0.142** (0.073) | −0.033 (0.086) | 0.178 (0.081) | 0.089 (0.103) |
CTP × previously held permanent job in CTP × holds permanent job | −0.908** (0.436) | 0.096 (0.407) | −1.075* (0.555) | −0.029 (0.415) |
Previously held permanent job in CTP × holds permanent job | 0.866** (0.476) | −0.109 (0.393) | 1.006* (0.599) | −0.0454 (0.398) |
average sample size (per pair) | 114156 | 163325 | 114212 | 165508 |
0.37 | 0.37 | 0.39 | 0.40 |
For income (column 3), we see a redistribution away from newly hired temporary workers towards newly hired permanent workers. Although the results on individually affected workers are significant at 10%, we see redistribution. This seems to counter the general equilibrium effect as workers that are eligible and have a permanent job seem to be worse off in CTP regions. At the same time, eligible workers seem to be better off in and outside CTP regions when they obtain permanent jobs. A worker outside a CTP region makes approximately 50% more if they are newly hired35
Such workers are hired late in the year and cannot earn as much, inflating the estimates. This is reflected in insignificant results for the stock as workers have the same time to earn.
Revenue, reported in table A1 in appendix A, was summed for each firm in the treatment and control groups and averaged. Values were normalized by the 2005 value. There is a reduction of approximately 2.8% in the treatment group in 2006 versus 2005 and even in 2007 the treatment group recovered to reach the output level of 2005. The control group's output, however, was higher by 0.9% in 2006, and in 2007 it was 7%. This is evidence of diminished economic activity in treatment areas.
This study developed a DMP-style matching model featuring a dual labour market with DRS in production. Central features of dual labour markets, such as coexisting permanent and temporary contracts, lower surplus for temporary workers, and tenure-dependent dismissal taxes for permanent workers are reproduced, and a link is made between permanent and temporary workers where temporary workers exist to buffer permanent workers from adverse productivity shocks and consequent downsizing. Generally, temporary workers are fired more often, which, together with lower surplus and/or wages, raises the question why workers would take such a job. Most models of dual labour markets explain this with ex-ante or ex-post heterogeneity. The key mechanism is that unemployed workers apply for lower-wage temporary jobs but are compensated by higher matching rates, consistent with observed patterns. The empirical predictions of the model regarding an increase in initial dismissal taxes, are that the ratio of permanent workers relative to total employment will be lower, but hazard rates of permanent matches out of employment will remain unaffected.
These predictions are tested using a labour market experiment in France, the CTP, exploiting matched DADS and EAE-ESANE datasets. The results support the model. CTP areas exhibit less employment and there is a reduction in the hiring of permanent workers in treatment areas of between 2 to 10 percentage points. The overall stock of workers is lower, which is statistically significant. Temporary workers are hired later, constituting a reduction in their use. A 7.5% increase in wages for workers leverages the increased separation taxes and provides stronger support. There is no significant impact on wages for workers eligible for the policy before their current match, so the policy itself did not impact the quality of the matches, likely due to the experimental nature of the policy. More supportive of the model is that hazard rates for permanent workers do not go down.36. Lower output in CTP areas reinforces this conclusion.
Workers improved their bargaining position at the cost of fewer permanent jobs and a lower aggregate duration of matches. Importantly, permanent workers are shielded from firing by temporary workers. Separation taxes do not seem to influence job security in dual labour markets for any contract type but increase the gulf between them and create more temporary contracts. This is consistent with the argument put forward by Blanchard and Tirole (2003) that reducing the protection gap between temporary and permanent workers would be beneficial to those trapped in temporary positions now. Unfortunately, the policy exacerbated the duality of the labour markets, which stems from linking a proactive policy with separation taxes. This strongly highlights the necessity to carefully consider financing and its interplay with institutions.
Figure 1

Figure 2

Figure 3

Figure 4

Figure 5

Figure 6

Figure 7

Figure 8

Hours worked and total income
CTP zone (post 15.4.2006) | 0.043 (0.088) | 0.070 (0.074) | 0.031 (0.071) | 0.154 (0.099) |
CTP × permanent job | −0.092 (0.084) | −0.042 (0.107) | −0.087 (0.108) | −0.156 (0.184) |
CTP × new firm | −0.432** (0.241) | −0.116 (0.426) | −0.469** (0.233) | −0.169 (0.399) |
CTP × firm below 1000 | −0.016 (0.132) | −0.02 (0.085) | 0.014 (0.128) | −0.093 (0.077) |
CTP × firm below 1000 × permanent job | 0.063 (0.147) | −0.018 (0.119) | −0.003 (0.144) | 0.072 (0.137) |
CTP × new firm × permanent job | 0.636*** (0.269) | 0.045 (0.337) | 0.591** (0.281) | 0.176 (0.296) |
CTP × previously held permanent job in CTP | 0.509* (0.349) | −0.018 (0.386) | 0.537* (0.387) | 0.011 (0.385) |
Previously held permanent job in CTP | −0.502* (0.358) | 0.178 (0.386) | −0.557 (0.401) | 0.176 (0.389) |
CTP × previously held permanent job × holds permanent job | 0.142** (0.073) | −0.033 (0.086) | 0.178 (0.081) | 0.089 (0.103) |
CTP × previously held permanent job in CTP × holds permanent job | −0.908** (0.436) | 0.096 (0.407) | −1.075* (0.555) | −0.029 (0.415) |
Previously held permanent job in CTP × holds permanent job | 0.866** (0.476) | −0.109 (0.393) | 1.006* (0.599) | −0.0454 (0.398) |
average sample size (per pair) | 114156 | 163325 | 114212 | 165508 |
0.37 | 0.37 | 0.39 | 0.40 |
Impact on hourly Wages
CTP zone (post 15.4.2006) | 0.003 (0.01) | 0.056 (0.036) | −0.014 (0.026) | 0.015 (0.033) | −0.015 (0.021) | 0.014 (0.032) | −0.014 (0.027) | 0.015 (0.025) |
CTP × permanent job | −0.039 (0.03) | 0.074* (0.042) | 0.008 (0.043) | −0.048 (0.04) | 0.004 (0.040) | −0.049 (0.038) | 0.0004 (0.043) | −0.05 (0.035) |
CTP × firm below 1000 | 0.03 (0.028) | 0.006 (0.022) | 0.031 (0.022) | 0.006 (0.022) | 0.03 (0.026) | 0.006 (0.018) | ||
CTP × firm below 1000 × permanent job | −0.067* (0.039) | 0.013 (0.029) | −0.065* (0.036) | 0.013 (0.024) | −0.064* (0.037) | 0.013 (0.032) | ||
CTP × previously held permanent job | 0.0279* (0.0144) | 0.059*** (0.022) | 0.012 (0.014) | 0.0026 (0.031) | ||||
CTP × previously held permanent job × holds permanent job | 0.04* (0.023) | 0.075*** (0.029) | ||||||
CTP × previously held permanent job in CTP × permanent job | −0.164 (0.123) | −0.132 (0.081) | ||||||
average sample size (per pair) | 113938 | 162996 | 113938 | 162996 | 113938 | 162996 | 113938 | 162996 |
0.41 | 0.49 | 0.42 | 0.49 | 0.42 | 0.49 | 0.42 | 0.50 |
j.izajolp-2023-0003.tab.005
2005 | 1 | 1 |
2006 | 0.972 | 1.009 |
2007 | 0.997 | 1.067 |
Impact on Duration
CTP zone (after 15.4.2006) | 0.067 (0.06) | 0.105 (0.107) | 0.063 (0.087) | 0.057 (0.087) | 0.053 (0.080) | 0.059 (0.108) | 0.054 (0.101) | 0.062 (0.127) |
CTP × permanent job | −0.080 (0.074) | −0.131 (0.13) | −0.027 (0.117) | −0.012 (0.117) | −0.049 (0.106) | −0.009 (0.159) | −0.244** (0.116) | −0.013 (0.161) |
CTP × new firm | −0.509*** (0.186) | 0.002 (0.186) | −0.506*** (0.175) | −0.009 (0.367) | −0.506*** (0.179) | −0.013 (0.337) | ||
CTP × firm below 1000 | 0.064 (0.148) | 0.057 (0.148) | 0.066 (0.141) | 0.055 (0.133) | 0.066 (0.137) | 0.053 (0.126) | ||
CTP × firm below 1000 × permanent job | −0.115 (0.196) | −0.129 (0.196) | −0.113 (0.176) | −0.126 (0.184) | −0.112 (0.159) | −0.125 (0.159) | ||
CTP × new firm × permanent job | 0.578* (0.319) | −0.074 (0.319) | 0.548* (0.305) | −0.055 (0.361) | 0.544* (0.308) | −0.052 (0.333) | ||
Previously held permanent job in CTP × currently holds permanent job | 0.046 (0.307) | 0.172 (0.339) | ||||||
average sample size (per pair) | 114187 | 163508 | 114187 | 163508 | 114187 | 163508 | 114187 | 163508 |
0.24 | 0.29 | 0.24 | 0.29 | 0.24 | 0.30 | 0.25 | 0.31 |
CTP versus control zones, pre-policy characteristics
Stock of Permanent Workers | 67.1% (4.64) | 66.9% (1.39) | 65.1% (5.87) |
Manufacturing Share | 20.8% (11.2) | 20.0% (11.5) | 19.6% (9.1) |
Services Share | 71.9% (11.35) | 79.0% (11.5) | 78.1% (9.6) |
Unemployment | 9.3% (5.4) | 10.4% (4.5) | 8.0% (6.3) |
Change in Unemployment since 04 | −0.66% (0.544) | −0.04% (0.35) | −0.30% (6.3) |
Permanent Share Predicted by Productivity Proxy | 57.2% (1.7) | 57.4% (1.2) | 57.0% (2.6) |
Participation Rate | 70.7% (4.7) | 70.6% (4.4) | 71.4% (2.8) |
Proportion of Unqualified Workers | 17.7% (4.38) | 14.8% (3.8) | 14.6% (3.9) |
Average Age of Workers | 39.2 (0.7) | 38.6 (0.3) | 39.5 (0.8) |
Average hourly Wages in 05 (Euro) | 14.22 (0.81) | 14.01 (0.73) | 14.55 (2.78) |
Average Gross Income in 05 (Euro) | 14258.76 (1207) | 14023.09 (743) | 13732 (1976) |
Non-Residents in Workforce | 48.8% (18.0) | 52.6% (8.95) | 70.5% (27.2) |
Locals with Local Job | 79.5% (9.6) | 78.1% (4.65) | 67.8% (19.6) |
Hazard Rates
CTP zone (post 15.4.2006) | −0.100 (0.142) | 0.018 (0.091) | 0.011 (0.243) | 0.218 (0.316) | 0.0148 (0.24) | 0.243 (0.252) | 0.007 (0.218) | 0.236 (0.272) |
CTP × permanent job | 0.142 (0.184) | −0.037 (0.087) | 0.039 (0.326) | −0.179 (0.251) | 0.063 (0.354) | −0.183 (0.249) | 0.073 (0.276) | −0.176 (0.218) |
CTP × firm below 1000 | −0.168 (0.212) | −0.162 (0.338) | −0.172 (0.212) | −0.171 (0.255) | −0.172 (0.199) | −0.16 (0.295) | ||
CTP × firm below 1000 × permanent job | −0.433* (0.223) | 0.159 (0.255) | 0.142 (0.218) | 0.166 (0.232) | 0.144 (0.193) | 0.155 (0.203) | ||
CTP × previously held permanent job | −0.096 (0.108) | −0.157 (0.187) | –0.084 (0.113) | –0.138 (0.204) | ||||
CTP × previously held permanent job × holds permanent job | −1.496* *(0.7) | 0.535 (1.6) | ||||||
CTP × previously held permanent job in CTP × holds permanent job | 1.201* (0.705) | −0.442 (1.567) | ||||||
average sample size (per pair) | 114187 | 163508 | 114187 | 163508 | 114187 | 163508 | 114187 | 163508 |
0.106 | 0.069 | 0.126 | 0.087 | 0.132 | 0.108 | 0.132 | 0.109 |
Various Distance Measures of CTP zones in comparison to France and the Control Group
Euclidian Distance | 34.75 | 31.87 |
Size Distance | 10.67 | 9.13 |
Correlation | 0.95 | 0.96 |
Correlation Transformed to Euclidian Distance | 0.2 | 0.18 |
Squared Correlation | 0.91 | 0.93 |
Chebychev Distance | 25.19 | 22.24 |
Manhattan Distance | 23.46 | 19.13 |
Shape Distance Component 1 | 3.13E-15 | 4.34E-15 |
Shape Distance Component 2 | 32.98 | 30.15 |
Shape Distance Component 3 | 3.29E-15 | 3.22E-15 |