Open Access

Microeconomic Foundation for Phillips Curve with a Three-Period Overlapping Generations Model and Negative Real Balance Effect


Cite

Introduction

Otaki and Tamai (2012) presented a microeconomic foundation of the negative relation between the unemployment rate and the inflation rate, that is, the Phillips Curve (Phillips, 1958) using an overlapping generations (OLG) model under monopolistic competition. They showed that, the lower the unemployment rate in a period (e.g., period t−1), the higher the inflation rate from period t to period t−1. Their logic is as follows. They assumed that the low (or high) unemployment rate in period t−1 increases (or decreases) the labour productivity in period t by learning effect. If the unemployment rate in period t−1 increases, the labour productivity in period t falls. Then, by the behaviour of firms in monopolistic competition, the price of the goods in period t rises given nominal wage rate, and the inflation rate from period t to period t+1 falls given the (expected) price of the goods in period t+1. Alternatively, a decrease in the unemployment rate in period t−1 increases the labour productivity in period t. Then, the price of the goods falls, and the inflation rate from period t to period t+1 increases given the (expected) price of the goods in period t+1. However, we do not find their conclusion that the low unemployment rate in period t−1 explains the high inflation rate from period t to period t+1 to be satisfactory. A fall in the price in period t means that the inflation rate from period t−1 to period t falls, that is, the low unemployment rate in period t−1 explains the low (not high) inflation rate from period t−1 to period t in their model.

Instead, in this article, we consider the effects of a change in the nominal wage rate with negative real balance effect. We use a three-period (three generations) OLG model with childhood period, younger period and older period. Also, we consider a pay-as-you-go pension system for the older generation to bring about negative real balance effect of a fall in the nominal wage rate. The negative real balance effect (or negative Pigou effect) means that by falls in the nominal wage rate and the price of the goods the real asset of consumers (difference between net savings and debts multiplied by marginal propensity to consume) decreases. The net savings of consumers is the difference between the consumption of consumers in Period 2 (when they are old) and pay-as-you-go pensions.

We will show the negative relationship between the unemployment rate and the inflation rate in the same period. Our logic is as follows. If the nominal wage rate in a period, for example, period t falls, the price of the goods falls. This means that the inflation rate from period t−1 to period t decreases. By the negative real balance effect, the aggregate demand for the goods and employment decreases and the unemployment rate increases in period t. Alternatively, if the nominal wage rate in period t rises, the price of the goods rises, and the inflation rate from period t−1 to period t increases. By the negative real balance effect, the aggregate demand for the goods and employment increases and the unemployment rate decreases in period t. For details, refer Section 4.

There are various studies on the theoretical basis of the Phillips curve from the neoclassical and new Keynesian standpoint. The representative of neoclassical studies is given (Lucas 1972). The neoclassical Phillips curve based on the rational expectation hypothesis is vertical at the natural unemployment rate, but in the short run, incomplete information leads to a downward sloping Phillips curve as firms increase production and employment without realising that the increase in the price of their goods reflects an increase in the general price level. In the new Keynesian analysis, the sticky nature of prices brought about by multi-year wage contracts (Taylor, 1979, 1980) and the sticky pricing behaviour of firms (Calvo, 1983) brings about a downward Phillips curve. Erceg, Henderson and Levin (1998, 2000) developed a similar analysis with a model that incorporates not only price but also wage stickiness, and Woodford (2003) developed an analysis using a model that incorporates an indexation rule such that pricing is linked to the historical inflation rate.

These works on the Phillips curve presume some market imperfection, and it implies that if there does not exist some price stickiness assumption or imperfect information, the negative correlation between inflation and unemployment will disappear. This article will show that it is not.

In Section 2, we analyse the behaviours of consumers and firms. In Section 3, we consider the equilibrium of the economy with involuntary unemployment. In Section 4, we show the main results about the negative relation between the unemployment rate and the inflation rate due to a change in the nominal wage rate. We also examine the effects of fiscal policy financed by seigniorage, which is represented as left-ward shift of the Phillips curve.

Behaviours of Consumers and Firms

We consider a three-period (childhood, young and old) OLG model under monopolistic competition. It is an extension and arrangement of the model (Otaki 2007, 2009, 2011, 2015). There is one factor of production, labour, and there is a continuum of goods indexed by z ∈[0,1]. Each good is monopolistically produced by Firm z. Consumers live over three periods: period 0 (childhood period), period 1 (younger period) and period 2 (older period). There are consumers of three generations, childhood, younger and older generations, at the same time. They can supply only one unit of labour when they are young (period 1).

Consumers

We use the following notations.

ci (z): consumption of good z in period i, i = 1, 2.

pi (z): price of good z in period, i, i = 1, 2.

Xi : consumption basket in period, i, i = 1, 2. Xi={01ci(z)11ηdz}111η,i=1,2,η>1. {X^i}={\left\{ {\int_0^1 {{c^i}{{\left( z \right)}^{1 - {1 \over \eta }}}dz} } \right\}^{{1 \over {1 - {1 \over \eta }}}}},\,i = 1,2,\eta > 1.

c0 (z): consumption of good z in period 0. It is constant.

p0 (z): price of good z in period 0. We assume p0 (z) = 1

X0={01c0(z)11ηdz}111η {X^0}={\left\{ {\int_0^1 {{c^0}{{\left( z \right)}^{1 - {1 \over \eta }}}dz} } \right\}^{{1 \over {1 - {1 \over \eta }}}}} It is constant.

X0′: consumption basket in the childhood period of a consumer of the next generation.

β: disutility of labour, β > 0.

W: nominal wage rate.

Π: profits of firms that are equally distributed to the younger generation consumers.

L : employment of each firm and the total employment.

Lf: population of labour or employment in the full-employment state.

y (L): labour productivity. y (L) ≥ 1.

R : unemployment benefit for an unemployed consumer, R = X0.

R′: unemployment benefit for an unemployed consumer in the next generation, R′ = X0′.

Θ: the tax for unemployment benefit.

φ: pay-as-you-go pension for a consumer of the older generation.

φ′: pay-as-you-go pension for a consumer of the younger generation when he is retired.

ψ: the tax for pay-as-you-go pension.

Consumers in period 0 consume the goods by borrowing money from consumers of the previous generation or the government (e.g. scholarship). They must repay the debts when they are young. However, if they are unemployed, they cannot repay the debts. Then, they receive the unemployment benefits, which are covered by taxes on employed younger generation consumers. Thus, employed younger generation consumers must pay the taxes for unemployment benefit as well as they must repay their own debts. R and Θ satisfy the following relation. (LfL)R=LΘ. \left( {{L_f} - L} \right)R = L\Theta . In addition, we consider the existence of pay-as-you-go pension for consumers of the older generation. They are also covered by taxes on employed consumers of the younger generation. Θ and ψ satisfy LfΦ=LΨ. {L_f}\Phi = L\Psi . Consumptions in period 0 of the consumers are constant, and in period 1, they determine their consumptions in periods 1 and 2 and their labour supply. δ is the definition function. If a consumer is employed, then δ = 1; if he is not employed, then δ = 0. The labour productivity is y(L). We consider increasing or constant returns to scale technology. Thus, y(L) is increasing or constant with respect to the employment of a firm L. We define the employment elasticity of the labour productivity as follows: ζ=yy(L)L. \zeta = {{y'} \over {{{y\left( L \right)} \over L}}}. 0 ≤ ζ < 1, and it is constant. Increasing returns to scale means η > 0. η is (the inverse of) the degree of differentiation of the goods. In the limit when η→+∞, the goods are homogeneous. h and ζ satisfy (11η)(1+ζ)<1 \left( {1 - {1 \over \eta }} \right)\left( {1 + \zeta } \right) < 1 so that the profits of firms are positive.

The utility of consumers of one generation over three periods is U(X0,X1,X2,δ,β)=u(X0,X1,X2)δβ. U\left( {{X^0},{X^1},{X^2},\delta ,\beta } \right) = u\left( {{X^0},{X^1},{X^2}} \right) - \delta \beta . u(X0, X1, X2) is homogeneous of degree one (linearly homogeneous) with respect to X1 and X2. Note that X0 is constant. The budget constraint is 01p1(z)c1(z)dz+01p2(z)c2(z)dz=δW+Π+ΦδRδ(Θ+Ψ). \matrix{ {\int_0^1 {{p^1}\left( z \right){c^1}\left( z \right)dz + } \int_0^1 {{p^2}\left( z \right){c^2}\left( z \right)dz = } } \hfill \cr {\delta W + \Pi + \Phi ' - \delta R - \delta \left( {\Theta + \Psi } \right).} \hfill \cr } p2(z) is the expectation of the price of good z in period 2. Note that R = X0. The Lagrange function is =u(X0,X1,X2)δβλ(01p1(z)c1(z)dz+01p2(z)c2(z)dzδWΠΦ+δR+δ(Θ+Ψ)). \matrix{ {{\cal L} = u\left( {{X^0},{X^1},{X^2}} \right) - \delta \beta - \lambda \left( {\int_0^1 {{p^1}\left( z \right){c^1}\left( z \right)dz + } } \right.} \hfill \cr {\left. {\int_0^1 {{p^2}\left( z \right){c^2}\left( z \right)dz - } \delta W - \Pi - \Phi ' + \delta R + \delta \left( {\Theta + \Psi } \right)} \right).} \hfill \cr } λ is the Lagrange multiplier. The first-order conditions are uX1(01(c1z)11ηdz)1η11ηc1(z)1η=λp1(z) {{\partial u} \over {\partial {X^1}}}{\left( {\int_0^1 {{{\left( {{c^1}\,z} \right)}^{1 - {1 \over \eta }}}dz} } \right)^{{{{1 \over \eta }} \over {1 - {1 \over \eta }}}}}{c^1}{\left( z \right)^{{1 \over \eta }}} = \lambda {p^1}\left( z \right) and uX2(01(c2z)11ηdz)1η11ηc2(z)1η=λp2(z) {{\partial u} \over {\partial {X^2}}}{\left( {\int_0^1 {{{\left( {{c^2}\,z} \right)}^{1 - {1 \over \eta }}}dz} } \right)^{{{{1 \over \eta }} \over {1 - {1 \over \eta }}}}}{c^2}{\left( z \right)^{- {1 \over \eta }}} = \lambda {p^2}\left( z \right) They are rewritten as uX1X1(01c1(z)11ηdz)1c1(z)11η=λp1(z)c1(z), {{\partial u} \over {\partial {X^1}}}{X^1}{\left( {\int_0^1 {{c^1}{{\left( z \right)}^{1 - {1 \over \eta }}}dz} } \right)^{ - 1}}{c^1}{\left( z \right)^1}^{ - {1 \over \eta }} = \lambda {p^1}\left( z \right){c^1}\left( z \right), uX2X2(01(c2z)11ηdz)1c2(z)11η=λp2(z)c2(z) {{\partial u} \over {\partial {X^2}}}{X^2}{\left( {\int_0^1 {{{\left( {{c^2}\,\,z} \right)}^{1 - {1 \over \eta }}}dz} } \right)^{ - 1}}{c^2}{\left( z \right)^1}^{ - {1 \over \eta }} = \lambda {p^2}\left( z \right){c^2}\left( z \right) Let P1=(01p1(z)1ηdz)11η,P2=(01p2(z)1ηdz)11η. {P^1} = {\left( {\int_0^1 {{p^1}{{\left( z \right)}^{1 - \eta }}dz} } \right)^{{1 \over {1 - \eta }}}},\,{P^2} = {\left( {\int_0^1 {{p^2}{{\left( z \right)}^{1 - \eta }}dz} } \right)^{{1 \over {1 - \eta }}}}. They are price indices of the consumption baskets in periods 1 and 2. By some calculations, we obtain (see Appendix A) u(X0,X1,X2)=λ[01p1(z)c1(z)dz+01p2(z)c2(z)dz]=λ[δW+Π+ΦδRδ(Θ+Ψ)], \matrix{ {u\left( {{X^0},{X^1},{X^2}} \right) = \lambda \left[ {\int_0^1 {{p^1}\left( z \right){c^1}\left( z \right)dz + \int_0^1 {{p^2}\left( z \right){c^2}\left( z \right)dz} } } \right]} \hfill \cr { = \lambda \left[ {\delta W + \Pi + \Phi ' - \delta R - \delta \left( {\Theta + \Psi } \right)} \right],} \hfill \cr } P2P1=uX2uX1 {{{P^2}} \over {{P^1}}} = {{{{\partial u} \over {\partial {X^2}}}} \over {{{\partial u} \over {\partial {X^1}}}}} and P1X1+P2X2=δW+Π+ΦδRδ(Θ+Ψ). {P^1}{X^1} + {P^2}{X^2} = \delta W + \Pi + \Phi ' - \delta R - \delta \left( {\Theta + \Psi } \right). The indirect utility of consumers is written as follows: V=1φ(P1,P2)[δW+Π+ΦδRδ(Θ+Ψ)]δβ. V = {1 \over {\varphi \left( {{P^1},{P^2}} \right)}}\left[ {\delta W + \Pi + \Phi ' - \delta R - \delta \left( {\Theta + \Psi } \right)} \right] - \delta \beta . ϕ(P1, P2) is a function which is homogeneous of degree one. The reservation nominal wage rate WR is a solution of the following equation. 1φ(P1,P2)[WR+Π+ΦRΘΨ]β=1φ(P1,P2)(Π+Φ). \matrix{ {{1 \over {\varphi \left( {{P^1},{P^2}} \right)}}\left[ {{W^R} + \Pi + \Phi ' - R - \Theta - \Psi } \right] - \beta = } \hfill \cr {{1 \over {\varphi \left( {{P^1},{P^2}} \right)}}\left( {\Pi + \Phi '} \right).} \hfill \cr } From this, we have WR=φ(P1,P2)β+R+Θ+Ψ. {W^R} = \varphi \left( {{P^1},{P^2}} \right)\beta + R + \Theta + \Psi . The labour supply is indivisible. If W > WR, the total labour supply is Lf. If W < WR, it is zero. If W = WR, then employment and unemployment are indifferent for consumers, and there exists no involuntary unemployment even if L < Lf.

Indivisibility of labour supply may be due to the fact that there exists minimum standard of living even in the advanced economy (Otaki, 2015).

Let ρ=P2P1 \rho = {{{P^2}} \over {{P^1}}} . This is the expected inflation rate (plus one). Since ϕ(P1, P2) is homogeneous of degree one, the reservation real wage rate is ωR=WRP1=φ(1,ρ)β+R+Θ+ΨP1. {\omega ^R} = {{{W^R}} \over {{P^1}}} = \varphi \left( {1,\rho } \right)\beta + {{R + \Theta + \Psi } \over {{P^1}}}. If the value of ρ is given, ωR is constant.

Otaki (2007) assumes that the wage rate equals the reservation wage rate in the equilibrium. However, there exists no mechanism to equalise them.

Firms

Let α=P1X1P1X1+P2X2=X1X1+ρX2,0<α<1. \alpha = {{{P^1}{X^1}} \over {{P^1}{X^1} + {P^2}{X^2}}} = {{{X^1}} \over {{X^1} + \rho {X^2}}},0 < \alpha < 1.

By some calculations, we obtain the demand for good z of a consumer of the younger generation as follows (see Appendix B): c1(z)=α[δW+Π+ΦδRδ(Θ+Ψ)]P1(p1(z)P1)η. {c^1}\left( z \right) = {{\alpha \left[ {\delta W + \Pi + \Phi ' - \delta R - \delta \left( {\Theta + \Psi } \right)} \right]} \over {{P^1}}}{\left( {{{{p^1}\left( z \right)} \over {{P^1}}}} \right)^{ - \eta }}. Similarly, his demand for good z in period 2 is c2(z)=(1α)[δW+Π+ΦδRδ(Θ+Ψ)]P2(p1(z)P2)η. {c^2}\left( z \right) = {{\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left[ {\delta W + \Pi + \Phi ' - \delta R - \delta \left( {\Theta + \Psi } \right)} \right]} \over {{P^2}}}{\left( {{{{p^1}\left( z \right)} \over {{P^2}}}} \right)^{ - \eta }}. Let M be the total savings of consumers of the older generation carried over from their period 1. It is written as M=(1α)[WL¯+LfΠ¯+LfΦL¯R¯L¯(Θ¯+Ψ¯)]. M = \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left[ {\overline {WL} + {L_f}\bar \Pi + {L_f}\Phi - \bar L\bar R - \bar L\left( {\bar \Theta + \bar \Psi } \right)} \right]. , and Π¯ \bar \Pi are nominal wage rate, employment and profit in the previous period, respectively. , Θ¯ \bar \Theta and Ψ¯ \bar \Psi are the unemployment benefit, tax for the unemployment benefit and tax for the pay-as-you-go pension in the previous period, respectively. Note that Φ is the pay-as-you-go pension for a consumer of the older generation. M is the total savings or the total consumption of the older generation consumers including the pay-as-you-go pensions they receive in their period 2. It is the planned consumption that is determined in period 1 of the older generation consumers. Net savings is the difference between M and the pay-as-you-go pensions in their period 2, which is written as follows: MLfΦ=(1α)[WL¯+LfΠ¯L¯R¯L¯(Θ¯+Ψ¯)]αLfΦ. \matrix{ {M - {L_f}\Phi = \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left[ {\overline {WL} + {L_f}\bar \Pi - \bar L\bar R - } \right.} \hfill \cr {\left. {\bar L\left( {\bar \Theta + \bar \Psi } \right)} \right] - \alpha {L_f}\Phi .} \hfill \cr } With this M, their demand for good z is MP1(p1(z)P1)η. {M \over {{P^1}}}{\left( {{{{p^1}\left( z \right)} \over {{P^1}}}} \right)^{ - \eta }}. The government expenditure constitutes the national income as well as consumptions of younger and older generations. The total demand for good z is written as c(z)=YP1(p1(z)P1)η. c\left( z \right) = {Y \over {{P^1}}}{\left( {{{{p^1}\left( z \right)} \over {{P^1}}}} \right)^{ - \eta }}. Y is the effective demand defined by Y=α[WL+LfΠ+LfΦLRL(Θ+Ψ)]+LfR+G+M. \matrix{ {Y = \alpha \left[ {WL + {L_f}\Pi + {L_f}\Phi ' - LR - L\left( {\Theta + \Psi } \right)} \right] + } \hfill \cr {{L_f}R' + G + M.} \hfill \cr } G is the government expenditure other than the pay-as-you-go pensions and the unemployment benefits, and R′ is the consumption in the childhood period of consumers of the next generation (about this demand function, see Otaki (2007, 2009)). The total employment, the total profits and the total government expenditure are written as follows: 01Ldz=L,01Πdz=Π,01Gdz=G. \int_0^1 {Ldz = L,} \int_0^1 {\Pi dz = \Pi ,} \int_0^1 {Gdz = G.} We have c(z)p1(z)=ηYP1p1(z)1η(P1)η=ηc(z)p1(z). {{\partial c\left( z \right)} \over {\partial {p^1}\left( z \right)}} = - \eta {Y \over {{P^1}}}{{{p^1}{{\left( z \right)}^{ - 1 - \eta }}} \over {{{\left( {{P^1}} \right)}^{ - \eta }}}} = - \eta {{c\left( z \right)} \over {{p^1}\left( z \right)}}. From c (z) = Ly (L), Lp1(z)=1y(L)+Lyc(z)p1(z). {{\partial L} \over {\partial {p^1}\left( z \right)}} = {1 \over {y\left( L \right) + Ly'}}{{\partial c\left( z \right)} \over {\partial {p^1}\left( z \right)}}. The profit of Firm z is π(z)=p1(z)c(z)Wy(L)c(z). \pi \left( z \right) = {p^1}\left( z \right)c\left( z \right) - {W \over {y\left( L \right)}}c\left( z \right). P1 is given for Firm z. Note that the employment elasticity of the labour productivity is ζ=yy(L)L. \zeta = {{y'} \over {{{y\left( L \right)} \over L}}}. The condition for profit maximisation with respect to p1 (z) is c(z)+[p1(z)1Ly1y(L)+Lyy(L)W]c(z)p1(z)==c(z)+[p1(z)Wy(L)+Ly]c(z)p1(z)=0. \matrix{ {c\left( z \right) + \left[ {{p^1}\left( z \right) - {{1 - Ly'{1 \over {y\left( L \right) + Ly'}}} \over {y\left( L \right)}}W} \right]{{\partial c\left( z \right)} \over {\partial {p^1}\left( z \right)}} = } \hfill \cr { = c\left( z \right) + \left[ {{p^1}\left( z \right) - {W \over {y\left( L \right) + Ly'}}} \right]{{\partial c\left( z \right)} \over {\partial {p^1}\left( z \right)}} = 0.} \hfill \cr } From this, we have p1(z)=Wy(L)+Lyc(z)c(z)p1(z)=W(1+ζ)y(L)+1ηp1(z). {p^1}\left( z \right) = {W \over {y\left( L \right) + Ly'}} - {{c\left( z \right)} \over {{{\partial c\left( z \right)} \over {\partial {p^1}\left( z \right)}}}} = {W \over {\left( {1 + \zeta } \right)y\left( L \right)}} + {1 \over \eta }{p^1}\left( z \right). Therefore, we obtain p1(z)=W(11η)(1+ζ)y(L). {p^1}\left( z \right) = {W \over {\left( {1 - {1 \over \eta }} \right)\left( {1 + \zeta } \right)y\left( L \right)}}. With increasing returns to scale, since ζ > 0, p1 (z) is lower than that in a case without increasing returns to scale given the value of W.

The Market Equilibrium
The equilibrium with involuntary unemployment

Since the model is symmetric, the prices of all goods are equal. Then, P1 = p1 (z).

Hence P1=W(11η)(1+ζ)y(L). {P^1} = {W \over {\left( {1 - {1 \over \eta }} \right)\left( {1 + \zeta } \right)y\left( L \right)}}. The real wage rate is ω=WP1=(11η)(1+ζ)y(L). \omega = {W \over {{P^1}}} = \left( {1 - {1 \over \eta }} \right)\left( {1 + \zeta } \right)y\left( L \right). Since ζ is constant, this is increasing or constant with respect to L.

The nominal aggregate supply of the goods equals WL+LfΠ=P1Ly(L). WL + {L_f}\Pi = {P^1}Ly\left( L \right). The nominal aggregate demand is α[WL+LfΠ+LfΦLRL(Θ+Ψ)]+LfR+G+M=αP1Ly(L)+α[LfΦLRL(Θ+Ψ)]+LfR+G+M \matrix{ {\alpha \left[ {WL + {L_f}\Pi + {L_f}\Phi ' - LR - L\left( {\Theta + \Psi } \right)} \right] + {L_f}R' + G + M} \hfill \cr { = \alpha {P^1}Ly\left( L \right) + \alpha \left[ {{L_f}\Phi ' - LR - L\left( {\Theta + \Psi } \right)} \right] + {L_f}R' + G + M} \hfill \cr } Since they are equal, P1Ly(L)=αP1Ly(L)+α[LfΦLRL(Θ+Ψ)]+LfR+G+M. \matrix{ {{P^1}Ly\left( L \right) = \alpha {P^1}Ly\left( L \right) + \alpha \left[ {{L_f}\Phi ' - LR - } \right.} \hfill \cr {\left. {L\left( {\Theta + \Psi } \right)} \right] + {L_f}R' + G + M.} \hfill \cr } From Eqs (1) and (2), we have (LfL)R=LΘ, \left( {{L_f} - L} \right)R = L\Theta , and LfΦ=LΨ. {L_f}\Phi = L\Psi . Therefore, we get P1Ly(L)=αP1Ly(L)+α(LfΦLfΦLfR)+LfR+G+M. \matrix{ {{P^1}Ly\left( L \right) = \alpha {P^1}Ly\left( L \right) + \alpha \left( {{L_f}\Phi ' - {L_f}\Phi - {L_f}R} \right) + } \hfill \cr {{L_f}R' + G + M.} \hfill \cr } This means P1Ly(L)=α(LfΦLfΦLfR)+LfR+G+M1α {P^1}Ly\left( L \right) = {{\alpha \left( {{L_f}\Phi ' - {L_f}\Phi - {L_f}R} \right) + {L_f}R' + G + M} \over {1 - \alpha }} In real terms Ly(L)=α(LfΦLfΦLfR)+LfR+G+MP1(1α), Ly\left( L \right) = {{\alpha \left( {{L_f}\Phi ' - {L_f}\Phi - {L_f}R} \right) + {L_f}R' + G + M} \over {{P^1}\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)}}, or L=α(LfΦLfΦLfR)+LfR+G+MP1(1α)y(L). L = {{\alpha \left( {{L_f}\Phi ' - {L_f}\Phi - {L_f}R} \right) + {L_f}R' + G + M} \over {{P^1}\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)y\left( L \right)}}. If we consider the tax T for the government expenditure, Eq. (13) is as follows: L=α(LfΦLfΦLfRT)+LfR+G+MP1(1α)y(L). L = {{\alpha \left( {{L_f}\Phi ' - {L_f}\Phi - {L_f}R - T} \right) + {L_f}R' + G + M} \over {{P^1}\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)y\left( L \right)}}. 11α {1 \over {1 - \alpha }} is a multiplier. Eqs (13) and (14) mean that the employment L is determined by g+m. It cannot be larger than Lf. However, it may be strictly smaller than Lf (L < Lf). Then, there exists involuntary umemployment. Since the real wage rate ω=(11η)(1+ζ)y(L) \omega = \left( {1 - {1 \over \eta }} \right)\left( {1 + \zeta } \right)y\left( L \right) is increasing or constant with respect to L, and the reservation real wage rate ωR is constant, if ω > ωR there exists no mechanism to reduce the difference between them.

Negative real balance effect

When the nominal wage rate falls, the price of the goods (price of consumption basket) falls. If the employment changes, the rate of a fall in the nominal wage rate and that of the price may be different in the case of increasing returns to scale. The real values of G, T, Φ, Φ′, R′ will not change even when the price of the goods falls. On the other hand, the nominal values of R and M-LfΦ will not change. Then, whether the aggregate demand increases or decreases when the nominal wage rate and the price of the goods fall depend on whether MLfΦαLfR M - {L_f}\Phi - \alpha {L_f}R is positive or negative. If MLfΦ−αLfR<0, there is a negative real balance effect (or Pigou effect)

About the traditional discussion of real balance effects, refer Pigou (1943) and Kalecki (1944).

such that a fall in the nominal wage rate decreases the aggregate demand because by a fall in the nominal wage rate the real asset of consumers (difference between net savings and debts multiplied by marginal propensity to consume) decreases. Alternatively, a rise in the nominal wage rate increases the aggregate demand.

Phillips Curve and Fiscal Policy
A change in the nominal wage rate with negative real balance effect

Suppose that the nominal wage rate falls in a period, for example, period t. From Eq. (11), the price of the goods also falls. Let Pt and Pt−1 be the price of the goods (price of the consumption basket) in period t and that in period t−1. The inflation rate from period t−1 to t, PtPt11 {{{P_t}} \over {{P_{t - 1}}}} - 1 , falls given Pt−1. If the negative real balance effect works, the real aggregate demand decreases. Then, the output and the employment decrease. Therefore, the lower inflation rate is accompanied by employment loss, that is, higher unemployment rate.

Alternatively, suppose that the nominal wage rate rises. The price of the goods also rises. If the negative real balance effect works, the real aggregate demand increases. Then, the output and the employment increase. Therefore, the higher price or higher inflation rate is accompanied by an increase in employment. Thus, we obtain a negative relationship between the inflation rate and the unemployment rate (positive relationship between the inflation rate and employment) as represented by the Phillips curve. We have shown a negative relationship between the inflation rate and the unemployment rate in the same period given the price in the previous period. Figure 1 depicts an example of the Phillips Curve. Ut denotes the unemployment rate in period t. Figure 1 implies that our model explains the inflation rate between periods t−1 and t by the unemployment rate in period t.

Fig. 1

Phillips curve

Fiscal policy

Let T be the tax revenue other than the taxes for the pay-as-you-go pension system and the unemployment benefits. Then, the budget constraint of the government is G=T, and the aggregate demand is αP1Ly(L)+α[LfΦLRL(Θ+Ψ)T]+LfR+G+MwithG=T. \matrix{ {\alpha {P^1}Ly\left( L \right) + \alpha \left[ {{L_f}\Phi ' - LR - L\left( {\Theta + \Psi } \right) - T} \right] + } \hfill \cr {{L_f}R' + G + M\,{\rm{with}}\,G = T.} \hfill \cr } With this, the aggregate demand Eq. (14) is L=α(LfΦLfΦLfRT)+LfR+G+MP1(1α)y(L) L = {{\alpha \left( {{L_f}\Phi ' - {L_f}\Phi - {L_f}R - T} \right) + {L_f}R' + G + M} \over {{P^1}\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)y\left( L \right)}} This implies that the balanced budget multiplier is one.

Given labour productivity y(L) and nominal wage rate W, the price of the goods P1 is determined by Eq. (11). If the government expenditure G increases given T, that is, an increment of the government expenditure is financed by seigniorage, from Eq. (16) employment L increases given the price P1. Then, the Phillips curve in Figure 1 shifts to the left as shown in Figure 2, the employment increases and the unemployment rate decreases given the inflation rate. With increasing returns to scale, y(L) is increasing with respect to L and the prices of the goods fall. However, employment will still increase.

Fig. 2

(a) Case of y‘(L)=0 (constant returns to scale) and (b) case of y‘(L)>0 (increasing returns to scale)

Fiscal policy—a fiscal-monetary policy

The money supply will increase by the difference between government expenditure and the tax. If the increase in the government expenditure is financed by seigniorage, it equals the increase in money supply. Therefore, the fiscal policy in this article is also a monetary policy. It should be called a fiscal-monetary policy. The increase in money supply does not raise the price. Thus, money is not neutral.

Otaki and Tamai (2012) suppose that the low (or high) unemployment rate in a period, for example, period t−1 raises (or lowers) the labour productivity in period t by learning effect. If the unemployment rate in period t−1 increases, the labour productivity in period t falls. Then, from Eq. (11), the price of the goods rises, and the inflation rate from period t to period t+1 falls given the (expected) price of the goods in period t+1. Alternatively, a decrease in the unemployment rate in period t−1 raises the labour productivity in period t. Then, the price of the goods falls, and the inflation rate from period t to period t+1 rises given the (expected) price of the goods in period t+1. Thus, they have shown the negative relation between the unemployment rate in period t−1 and the inflation rate from period t to period t+1, Pt+1Pt1 {{{P_{t + 1}}} \over {{P_t}}} - 1 . On the other hand, a fall in the price in period t means that the inflation rate from period t−1 to period t falls, that is, the low unemployment rate in period t−1 explains the low (not high) inflation rate from period t−1 to period t, PtPt11 {{{P_t}} \over {{P_{t - 1}}}} - 1 .

Their Phillips curve is depicted in Figure 3. Ut–1 denotes the unemployment rate in period t−1.

Fig. 3

Phillips curve by Otaki and Tamai (2012)

The thicker curve in Figure 3 means that the low unemployment rate in period t−1 explains the high inflation rate between periods t and t+1 in the model of Otaki and Tamai (2012). The thinner curve shows that the increase in the unemployment rate in period t−1 leads to the higher inflation rate between periods t−1 and t in their model.

Conclusion

We have shown that in a three-period OLG model under monopolistic competition changes in the nominal wage rate bring about the negative relation between the unemployment rate and the inflation rate in the same period. This conclusion is based on the premise of utility maximisation of consumers and profit maximisation of firms. Therefore, we have presented a microeconomic foundation of the Phillips curve. In the future research, we will conduct an empirical analysis of the relationship between the unemployment rate and the rate of inflation and the relationship between the rate of inflation (or the rate of deflation) and consumption expenditures to investigate the effect of the (negative) real balance effect on the shape of the Phillips curve.

There are other ideas that derive the Phillips curve based on the utility-maximising behaviour of consumers and profit-maximising behaviour of firms. Exogenous changes in labour productivity may be one of them. The logic is as follows. If the labour productivity in a period, for example, period t, increases, then the employment decreases and the unemployment rate in period t increases. An increase in labour productivity leads to a decrease in prices given nominal wage rate, and the inflation rate from period t−1 to period t decreases. Alternatively, if the labour productivity in period t decreases, the employment increases, and the unemployment rate in period t decreases. A decrease in labour productivity leads to an increase in prices given nominal wage rate, and the inflation rate from period t−1 to period t increases.

eISSN:
2543-6821
Language:
English