Open Access

Unemployment Impact of Product and Labor Market Regulation: Evidence from European Countries


Cite

Introduction

With almost 20 million people

Total number of people unemployed aged 15–74 years in 24 considered European countries.

unemployed in 2016, unemployment is and remains at the core of the economic and social debate in Europe. The financial crisis in 2008 and the sovereign debt crisis which followed in Europe in 2013 significantly raised the unemployment rate. Unemployment rates are particularly high in some countries: as much as 23.6% in Greece and 19.6% in Spain in 2016 compared to 8.4% and 8.2%, respectively, in 2007. Since standard macroeconomic tools such as monetary and fiscal policies are being already used and have their limits, structural reforms appear as a crucial ingredient for boosting economic growth and employment. This paper contributes to the debate by evaluating the effect of product and labor market deregulation on the unemployment rate.

The economy-wide product market regulation (PMR) index computed by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) is used to estimate the level of regulation in 24 European countries

Twenty-one countries from the European Union (EU; Austria, Belgium, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Poland, Portugal, Slovakia, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, and United Kingdom) as well as Iceland, Norway, and Switzerland.

over the period 1998–2013. The indicator covers all sectors and can be broken down by type of regulation thanks to the bottom-up approach used to compute it. State controls, barriers to entrepreneurship, and barriers to trade can thus be assessed separately to find the most relevant deregulation policy to put in place to tackle unemployment. Labor market regulation is analyzed through the OECD employment protection legislation (EPL) index, which can also be unbundled by type of contract (regular or temporary).

The timing of structural reform implementation can be directly linked to the economic environment, leading to an endogeneity issue. Standard econometric methodologies would then provide biased estimates since the change in the unemployment rate can be due to a cyclical component rather than to the implementation of product and labor market reforms. We control for the potential endogeneity of PMR and EPL by using a fixed-effect regression model, where lags of the difference with respect to the country means for the endogenous variables are used as instruments. Results show that a reduction in PMR reduces the unemployment rate whereas a drop in EPL increases it. Moreover, econometric tests do not support the existence of PMR and EPL endogeneity.

The increase in unemployment does not affect all categories of workers equally. Young workers, less educated individuals, and to a lesser extent women constitute vulnerable groups. Their average unemployment rates reached 18.2%, 16.2%, and 8.7%, respectively, in 2016 in Europe.

Average unemployment rate among the 24 European countries considered: total number of unemployed workers aged 15–74 years as a proportion of the total corresponding labor force.

These high unemployment rates encourage governments to implement targeted policies such as education improvement, reduction in childcare costs, and activation policies. In addition to these policies, it is interesting to assess the impact of structural reforms which are not specially designed to target vulnerable groups. We estimate the unemployment effect of PMR and EPL reforms by gender, age, and education of workers. Although men and women are equally affected, it appears that young workers and low- and middle-educated individuals are more affected by reforms than their counterparts.

A review of the existing literature on the effect of product and labor market reforms on unemployment is presented in Section 2. This review also highlights previous findings on different types of deregulations (PMR and EPL) and on different types of workers. We contribute significantly to the literature by analyzing a longer period of time than previous studies which notably allows us to control for the potential endogeneity of the regulatory variables and to obtain more efficient estimates. We also add to existing evidence by considering subcomponents of product and labor market reforms as well as by analyzing different groups of workers. Section 3 presents the database and defines PMR and EPL indices. It also describes which reforms took place in the past and analyzes the bivariate relationship between each index and the unemployment rate. Empirical results of the regression analysis are summarized in Section 4. We distinguish by type of deregulation as well as by type of workers. The last section concludes by emphasizing some limits of the study and proposes avenues for further research.

Literature review

Unemployment movements as well as heterogeneities across countries can largely be explained by interactions between macroeconomic shocks and economic institutions (Blanchard and Wolfers, 2000). PMR and EPL are part of the equation. The first section is devoted to theoretical and empirical findings regarding the labor impact of PMR and EPL. The second section summarizes the labor market situation, and in particular the unemployment rate, of different categories of workers and presents a survey of the literature on the labor impact of PMR and EPL for vulnerable groups.

Theoretical and empirical findings on the impact of product and labor market (de)regulation on labor market outcomes

In the theoretical literature, product market deregulation is usually defined as a reduction in barriers to entry or an increase in competition. Ebell and Haefke (2003) studied the dynamic relationship between product market entry regulation and equilibrium unemployment and wages. They assume matching frictions, monopolistic competition in the goods market, multi-worker firms, individual wage bargaining, and barriers to entry. They find a positive impact of product market deregulation on labor market outcomes: a reduction in entry barriers in the model brings down unemployment and pushes up wages.

Blanchard and Giavazzi (2003) distinguish between short-run and long-run effects. In their model, a reduction in entry costs has no effect in the short run since the number of firms is assumed to be fixed. The positive effect of deregulation comes only in the long run when new firms enter the market, implying a higher elasticity of demand and a lower markup. This in turn leads to lower unemployment and higher wages. Cacciatore et al. (2012) study the macroeconomic effects of a reduction in barriers to entry using a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model. They assume endogenous producer entry, equilibrium unemployment, and costly job creation and destruction. In line with Blanchard and Giavazzi (2003), their results show a long-term effect but no short-term effect.

The story is different if an increase in product market competition is considered. In the Blanchard and Giavazzi model, firms are then facing more elastic demand associated with a lower markup in the short run. This, in turn, leads to both an increase in real wages and a fall in unemployment. In the long run, profits come back to their initial level, as do unemployment and wages. Using a general equilibrium model, Gersbach and Schniewind (2001) evaluate the final effect of promoting product market competition, without any distinction between short-run and long-run impact. They find a decline in the aggregate unemployment rate (although the unemployment rate can rise in some sectors). Amable and Gatti (2001) consider an increase in product market competition in a model of monopolistic competition with an endogenous determination of worker flows in and out of unemployment. Product market reform boosts the hiring rate as well as the separation rate, which can lead to a negative effect on unemployment depending on wage rigidities in the labor market.

The empirical findings are in line with the theory and point to a decrease in unemployment (Amable et al. 2011, Bassanini and Duval 2006a, De Serres et al. 2012, Griffith et al. 2007) and an increase in employment (Berger and Danninger 2007, Boeri et al. 2000, Fiori et al. 2007, Nicoletti et al. 2001, Nicoletti and Scarpetta 2005) if the product market is deregulated. Gal and Hijzen (2016) and Bordon et al. (2016) evaluate the impact over time and find a positive and increasing effect in the long run. The methodologies and results are summarized in Table 1.

Summary of empirical findings on the impact of PMR and EPL reforms on (un)employment

StudiesDataDependent variableDefinition: PMR and EPLMethodologyEndogeneity testsResults
Boerietal. (2000)19 OECD countries, 1982-1995Nonagricultural employment rateEPL: OECD indicator for permanent and temporary workers PMR: OECD economy-wide indexStep 1: reduced-form model for EPL; step 2: country-specific effect; step 3: bivariate correlation between the unexplained country-specific effects and the PMR indexCountries with restrictive PMR tend to have lower employment rates in the nonagricultural business sector. EPL has a negative impact on employment rate (90% significance)
Nicoletti et al (2001)20 OECD countries, 1982-1998Employment ratePMR: OECD sectoral indexReduced-form models estimated with fixed and random effectsAnticompetitive PMR has significant negative effects on nonagricultural employment rate. In some countries, the product market regulatory environment may account for up to 3 PP of deviations of the employment rate from the OECD average
Baker et al (2002)20 OECO countries, 1960-1999Unemployment rateEPL: OECD indicatorFeasible generalized least squaresDo not consider EPL as endogenous. Control for the endogeneity of ALMPs by instrumenting it using countries' average ALMP value over the period 1985-1999No argument in favor of labor market deregulation since nearly all the change in structural unemployment rates was accounted for by country-specific effects not by institutional factors
Belot and Van Ours (2004)17 OECD countries, 1960-1999Unemployment rateEPL: index based on three subindexes (protection of open-ended contracts, fixed-term contracts, and temporary work agencies), own computation, scale of 0-1FE regressions taking interactions between labor market institutions into accountNo clear causal relationship between employment protection and unemployment rate. Estimating the regression with fixed effect made the coefficient of employment protection statistically insignificant
Nicoletti and Scarpetta (2005)20 OECD countries, 1980-2002Nonagricultural employment rateEPL: OECD indicator for permanent and temporary workers PMR: OECD sectoral indexFixed effect: regressionSignificant employment gains can be obtained by deregulating product markets in overly regulated countries. EPL has a negative impact on employment rate but this impact is not significant in all specifications, particularly when they control for outliers and add country fixed effects
Bassanini and Duval (2006a)20 OECD countries, 1982-2003Unemployment rateEPL: OECD indicator for permanent and temporary workers PMR: OECD sectoral indexFeasible GSL with fixed and random effectsIV estimation using lagged institutional variables (2-year lag) PMR and EPL coefficients become statistically insignificantPMR raise aggregates unemployment. EPL effect on unemployment is statistically insignificant
Berger and Danninger (2007)27OECD countries, 1980-2004Employment growth rateEPL: OECD indicator for permanent and temporary workers PMR: OECD economy-wide indexTime series panel techniques with fixed and random effects, IV and GMMGMM based on Arellano and Bond (1991) with a four-lag structure Same result as other specifications but coefficients become not statistically significantLower levels of product and labor market regulator foster employment growth
Fiori et al (2007)20 OECO countries, 1980-2002Nonagricul- tural employ- ment rateEPL: OECD indicator for permanent and tempo- rary workers PMR: OECD sectoral indexFeasible GLSControl function approach of Rivers and Vuong (1988) finds that there is no endog- eneity and thus GLS results are consistentAnticompetitive PMR has a negative impact on employment rate Tight labor market regulation tends to reduce employment
Griffith et al. (2007)14 OECO countries, 1986-2000Unemploy- ment ratePMR: captures changes in the extent of competition using a measure of the average level of firm profitability+2 indicators based on an opinion sur- vey and 1 reported by the Fraser InstituteFixed-effect regressionTwo-stage estimation approach: first, the impact of PMR and LMR on profitability, and then, the impact of profitability on the unemployment rateIncreased competition reduces unemployment
Kugler and Pica (2008)Italian Social Security employer- employee panel data, 1986-1995Accession or separation between worker and firmEPL: dummy variable which takes the value of 1 after 1990 (after the reform) and a dummy variable which takes the value of 1 if the worker is employed in a small firmDifference-in-difference approach by comparing worker and job flows in small and large firms before and after the reformUse the 1990 reform on workers and job flows (increasing dismissal costs for small firms) as a natural experimentThe increase in dismissal costs decreased accession and separation rates for workers in small relative to large firms. Negligible impact on net employment
Amable et al. (2011)18 OECD countries, 1930-2004Jobless, inactivity and unemploy- mentEPL: model the evolution of the OECD index using EPL index from the FRDB Social Reforms: Data- base as well as country dummies and time trends as regressors PMR: OECD index (economy wide and sectoral)Limited dependent variable model with country dum- mies + fixed-effect vector decompositionIV estimation using lagged institutional variables Finds that there is no endogeneityRegressions on joblessness show a negative impact of PMR and a positive impact of EPL on employment. Regression using sectoral PMR index shows not statistically significant impact on joblessness Specifications for inactivity and unemployment show that the model specification fits more satisfactorily the inactivity rather than the unemployment component of joblessness. Unemployment equation: PMR always positive and statistically significant (economy-wide index) and EPL negative but not statistically significant
De Serres et al. (2012)21 OECD countries, 1985-2007Unemploy- ment rateEPL: OECD indicator on regular contracts + share of workers with fixed- term contracts PMR: OECD sectoral indexDynamic unemployment equation taking the per- sistence of unemployment into account estimated using FE LSDV estimator + NLS estimatorDifference GMM: The impact of EPL on regular contracts remains positive and significant. However, the impact of PMR becomes negative and insignificantEasing of EPL on regular contracts reduces the persistence of unemployment (statistically significant only in half of the specifications including the one based on diff-GMM) More competition-friendly PMR can reduce structural unemployment but the impact is not robust to different specifications
Malk (2013)Micro- data from labor force survey for Es- tonia and Lithuania, 2007-2011Worker flows out from em- ployment and into employ- mentEPL: dummy variable which takes the value of 1 after the reform and a dummy variable which takes the value of 1 if the worker is in EstoniaDifference-in-difference approach by comparing labor flows in Lithuania and Estonia before and after the reformAnalyze the Estonian reform in mid-2009 decreasing EPL (for all workers) and use Lithuania as a controlLabor flows out of and into employment increased in Estonia relative to Lithuania. Statistically significant only for flows out of employment
Bordon et al. (2016)30 OECD countries, 1980-2013Variation in the employ- ment rate (from 1 to 5 years)EPL: OECD indicator on regular contracts PMR: OECD sectoral indexDefine two reform variables (for PMR and EPL) which take the value of 1 when the index drop by more than 2 standard deviations of the change in the indicator overall observations; esti- mation using local projections techniquesAIPW method that esti- mates the treatment effects of reforms while controlling for potential selection bias The positive effect of reforms remains ever after controlling for endogeneityStructural reforms have a lagged but positive impact on employment Both labor and product market reforms increase employment rates by about a little over 1% pain: over 5 years
Gal and Hijzen (2016)10 regulat- ed indus- tries in 18 advanced economies, 1998-2013Employment based on the firm-level da- tabase OrbisPMR OECD sectoral indexImpulse response function using the local projection methodInstrumental variablesProduct market reforms have positive effects on employment and their effects increase overtime

AIPW, augmented inverse probability weighting; ALMP, active labor market policies; EPL, employment protection legislation; FE, fixed effects; FRDB, Fondazione Rodolfo Debenedetti; GMM, generalized method of moments; GLS, generalized least squares; IV, instrumental variables; LMR, labor market regulations; LSDV, least-square dummy variable; NLS, nonlinear least square; PMR, product market regulation; pp, percentage points.

Depending on the type of product market deregulation implemented by governments, the expected impact on labor market outcomes can differ. Papers distinguish between state controls (e.g., public ownership), barriers to entrepreneurship (e.g., administrative burdens, regulatory opacity, and barriers to entry), and barriers to trade [e.g., barriers to Foreign Direct Investment (FDI)]. Regarding government interventions, results are contrasted. Although some papers find a negative but not statistically significant impact of state control on employment (Boeri et al. 2000, Berger and Danninger 2007), Fiori et al. (2007) find a statistically significant positive relationship. Nicoletti and Scarpetta (2005) analyze the nonagricultural business employment rate (excluding public employment) and find a negative and statistically significant effect of public ownership. This implies that employment shifts, at least partially, from business to public sector as a result of an increase in public ownership. Regarding barriers to entrepreneurship and barriers to trade, the evaluated impact is always negative: more regulation would mean less employment (Fiori et al. 2007, Berger and Danninger 2007) even if the effect is sometimes not statistically significant (Boeri et al. 2000).

Labor market factors, that is, union density, employment protection, replacement rate, and active labor market policies, are also at the core of unemployment researches. In this paper, we are particularly interested in EPL which aims to protect workers against abusive dismissals and provides (financial) compensation for the income loss associated with dismissals. Flexibility of employment protection is considered to be essential for rapid adjustments in the workforce to changing economic conditions and to reallocate labor toward more productive activities.

In theory, more stringent EPL is modeled through an increase in the cost of firing staff. A priori, labor demand is thus negatively affected: firms reduce their hiring rates and unemployment increases (Cahuc and Zylberberg, 1996, Bassanini and Duval 2006b). To compensate for higher dismissal costs, firms offer lower wages. However, severance pay can be seen as an additional income for workers. If workers are risk neutral, it does not matter if the income is coming from wages or severance pay. Wages adjust, and the unemployment rate is not affected (Burda 1992). On the other hand, as the hiring rate declines, the average time job seekers spend in unemployment before finding a new job increases and unemployment becomes more costly.

Workers are more willing to accept lower wages to maintain their jobs, and labor market equilibrium is restored (Blanchard 1999). As a result, employment protection lowers labor turnover (both hiring and layoffs) and extends the duration of unemployment. The net effect on the aggregate unemployment rate remains ambiguous.

Labor market deregulation through less stringent EPL can provide different results. In the short run, it leads to lower wages and thus higher profits for firms. It either has no effect on unemployment (Blanchard and Giavazzi 2003) or initially increases layoffs more than it creates jobs and thus increases unemployment (Cacciatore et al. 2016). In the long run, higher profits attract new firms which hire new workers and thus the unemployment rate drops.

Empirical estimates on the potential impact of EPL on (un)employment vary. Although some papers find a positive effect of EPL deregulation on employment (Bordon et al. 2016, Berger and Danninger 2007, Boeri et al. 2000, Fiori et al. 2007) and a fall in unemployment (De Serres et al. 2012), others find a statistically insignificant impact (Kugler and Pica 2008, Bassanini and Duval 2006a, Belot and Van Ours 2004, Amable et al. 2011, Nicoletti and Scarpetta 2005) or even a negative impact on employment (Malk 2013). Studying 20 OECD countries during the period 1960–1999, Baker et al. (2002) find that a large part of unemployment movements was mainly due to country-specific effects rather than institutional factors such as EPL. In sum, the empirics do not provide unambiguous results that could justify prescriptions for labor market deregulation. A detailed summary of the results and the estimation methods are provided in Table 1.

Employment protection reforms can be implemented either on regular or on temporary contracts and thus have different impacts on labor market outcomes. Bassanini and Duval (2006a) point out that a statistically insignificant aggregate impact of EPL on unemployment may mask two opposite effects. On the one hand, regulation on permanent contracts implies upward pressure on unemployment with a positive coefficient in the unemployment equation. On the other hand, stricter rules for temporary contracts can induce downward pressure on unemployment and a negative coefficient. However, both effects disappear when Spain is removed from the sample (Spain undertook the deepest reforms on permanent contracts over the period 1982–2003) and thus the empirical findings are not particularly robust. In a study of 21 OECD countries over the period 1985–2007, De Serres et al. (2012) also found a positive but not statistically significant impact of permanent contract regulation on unemployment and a statistically insignificant negative effect of the share of temporary contracts on unemployment. By contrast, when analyzing the change in employment, Berger and Danninger (2007) estimated a negative and statistically significant effect of regulation for all types of EPL but with a larger impact for permanent contracts and protection against collective dismissals than for temporary contracts.

The difference between the levels of regulation for both types of contracts can also be crucial in determining the potential variation of unemployment. A stricter protection for permanent contracts compared to temporary contracts could raise the share of temporary contracts. However, this conclusion also depends on the initial level of regulation. If employment protection is initially strict for both types of contracts, a weakening in rules for temporary contracts would raise the share of temporary contracts (Boeri et al. 2000). The reform of temporary contracts in Spain in 1984 is a good illustration since the use of fixed-term contracts dramatically increased from 10% at the beginning of the 1980s to 35% in the 1990s.

Vulnerable groups of workers and the potential effect of PMR and EPL

All averages in this section correspond to the average for the 24 European countries considered, namely 21 countries from the EU (Austria, Belgium, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Poland, Portugal, Slovakia, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, United Kingdom) + Iceland, Norway, and Switzerland.

Women, young workers, old workers, and the low-educated people are considered as vulnerable groups in terms of employment. A large share of those types of workers is either inactive or unemployed (Figure 1). The unemployment literature has widely studied the reasons behind their weaker attachment to the labor market.

Figure 1

Unemployment rate for different types of workers (2016, average of the 24 considered European countries, in the percentage of the corresponding labor force aged 15–74 years).

Source: EC.

Unemployment among young people appears to be one of the most highly sensitive variables in the labor market. It is directly linked to gross domestic product (GDP) growth: the youth unemployment rate falls during booms and rises during recessions. In addition, young workers are frequently mismatched in their employment (Shimer 2001). The employment process thus implies considerable searching and job changing before settling into a more or less permanent contract. In 2016, on average across European countries, 45% of the 15–24-year-old salaried workers had a temporary contract compared to 14% of the category aged 25–49 years. Job match improves with age, and older workers are often protected against job loss by seniority rights because they have built-up skills through experience. Despite job protection and the lower average unemployment rate, the possibilities of finding a new job decline with age. The net effect is that the long-term unemployment rate is higher for older workers. In 2016, 60% of the unemployed workers over 50 years had been disconnected from the labor market for more than 12 months in Europe. This rate was 28% for the age group of 15–24 years and 47% for the age group of 25–49 years.

In spite of the rise in their participation rate, from 52% in 1998 to 59% in 2016, there are still less women in the labor market than men, with a gap in the activity rate of 11 percentage points in 2016. As emphasized by Jaumotte (2004), education, the functioning of labor markets, and cultural attitudes (access to childcare, parental leave, integration) remain important determinants of female participation. Analyzing 18 OECD countries over the period 1980–2007, Thévenon (2013) finds that childcare services, maternity leave, and tax policies remain the most important drivers of increased female participation in the labor market.

Whatever the age or gender considered, unemployment is concentrated among those with the lowest level of education. Moreover, a large part of the increase in unemployment in Europe is due to a rise in joblessness among the low-skilled workers. The reason is a fall in demand for low-skilled workers. Competition from countries with low labor costs and technological progress are two factors often cited to explain labor demand shrinkage. However, as emphasized by Dolado et al. (2000), raising the educational attainment of the labor force does not always solve the unemployment problem unless other labor market rigidities are reduced.

Among the wide range of literature on product and labor market regulations, only very few articles have considered their impact on the unemployment rate for different categories of individuals. Gal and Theising (2015) point out that low-educated people, the young, and the elderly tend to be more affected by structural reforms. They study EPL in particular and find an heterogeneous impact on various segments of the population. In their analysis, stricter regulation reduces employment for women and low-educated workers and pushes up employment for highly educated individuals. Bassanini and Duval (2006b) also find contrasting results depending on the type of workers, with a decrease in employment for young workers but an increase for older workers. As emphasized in the OECD (2004)Employment Outlook, by reducing turnover, employment protection reduces the job prospects for those with relatively weak attachment to the labor market, such as young workers and women. Those opposing effects may explain the difficulty in finding a robust impact of EPL on aggregate unemployment since the impact depends on the composition of the working-age population in terms of skills and demographic characteristics. PMR seems to affect women more than men. Studying the impact of PMR on the employment rate for 20 OECD countries over the period 1982–2003, Bassanini and Duval (2006b) estimate a statistically significant negative effect for women but no statistically significant impact for men. De Serres et al. (2012) provide similar results by studying the unemployment rate: a stricter regulation implies a higher unemployment rate for women but not for men. Those two articles also find that the impact depends on the age of workers: PMR affects older workers positively, through an increase in their employment rate (Bassanini and Duval 2006b), but affects young people negatively, through an increase in the unemployment rate (De Serres et al. 2012).

Data

Our sample includes 24 European countries

Twenty-one countries from the EU (Austria, Belgium, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Poland, Portugal, Slovakia, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, United Kingdom) + Iceland, Norway, and Switzerland.

over the period 1998–2013.

Table of descriptive statistics for all variables is given in Supplementary materials.

The two variables of interest, that is, PMR and EPL, are OECD indicators. The PMR index

For more information on the PMR index, see Koske et al. (2015).

is updated every 5 years and currently covers the years 1998, 2003, 2008, and 2013. The OECD collects information on regulatory structures and policies through a questionnaire sent to governments. Each answer is normalized over a 0 to 6 scale, where a lower value means a low level of regulation. In a bottom-up approach, the numerical value of each question is first aggregated into 18 low-level indicators. They are then aggregated into seven mid-level indicators, which are in turn aggregated into three high-level indicators: state control, barriers to entrepreneurship, and barriers to trade and investment. An economy-wide indicator is then calculated based on the three high-level indicators (Figure 2). At each step of aggregation, a weighted average is used.

Figure 2

PMR indicator – OECD definition.

Source: OECD. EPL, employment protection legislation.

The indicators are insulated from context-specific assessments that are found in opinion surveys since they are based on objective data about laws and regulations. Although the procedure ensures that the indicators are comparable across countries and over time, it has only limited information on how authorities implement the regulation and on informal regulatory practices.

The same bottom-up approach is used in the computation of the EPL indicator. The index is available for the period 1985–2013 and is computed every year. It combines information on strictness of employment protection for regular contracts (individual and collective dismissals) and on the use of temporary contracts (Figure 3). The indicator is compiled on the basis of statutory laws, collective bargaining agreements, and case law, with contributions of country experts. It is scaled from 0 to 6 and rises with the level of strictness. Even though the complexity of EPL is difficult to summarize in an index, the EPL indicator provides a quantitative and comprehensive measure which is comparable across countries and over time.

Figure 3

EPL indicator – OECD definition.

Source: OECD. PMR, product market regulation.

As shown in Figure 4, over the past 15 years, product markets have been substantially liberalized in European countries: the average index fell from 2.22 in 1998 to 1.38 in 2013. Reforms took place in all countries analyzed, with the biggest reduction occurring in Poland (-1.54), Hungary (-1.34), and Portugal (-1.29). Despite the 1.29 drop, Poland remains one of the most regulated European countries in 2013: it ranks 22nd just ahead of Slovenia (23rd) and Greece (24th). The most competition-friendly in 2013 were the Netherlands, the United Kingdom, and Austria.

Figure 4

Product market reforms between 1998 and 2013 (change in the PMR OECD index).

Note: Luxembourg, Slovak Republic, Estonia, and Slovenia are not presented in the graph because data are not available at the beginning of the period.

Source: OECD. PMR, product market regulation.

In recent years, liberalization of the product market has slowed down in European countries. Between 1998 and 2003, the average PMR score fell by 0.46 compared to 0.26 between 2003 and 2008 and 0.14 between 2008 and 2013. The pace of reforms may have slowed down, because most countries have already reached a low level of regulation. The potential benefits of further reforms are thus becoming smaller, and liberalization becomes harder over time. Three countries even introduced additional rules that inhibit competition: Ireland (with an increase in the PMR indicator by +0.1 over the period 2008–2013), Iceland (+0.02), and Luxembourg (+0.02). On the other hand, Greece, Italy, and Spain faced strong market pressure for structural reforms in 2011. Although the PMR index for Greece came down by 0.47 points (the largest change over the period 2008–2013), reforms have been more modest in Italy (-0.22) and Spain (-0.15).

On average across European countries, deregulation has mostly involved removing barriers to entrepreneurship (from 2.72 in 1998 to 1.62 in 2013), through simplification of the regulatory procedures and reduced protection of incumbents (e.g., lower barriers to entry). State control was limited by abolishing price controls (or at least by making them more competition friendly). The state control index fell by 0.93 points and reached a level of 2.13 in 2013. Public ownership remains high at an index of 2.72. Barriers to trade and investment were already low in 1998 (0.87) and continued to come down over time (0.39 in 2013), mainly because of discrimination against foreign suppliers fall.

The trend in reducing regulations is less strong in labor markets than in product markets. Figure 5 shows that from an average score of 2.66 in 1998, European countries reached 2.46 in 2013. However, contrary to product market reforms, employment protection dropped back at an increasing rate over time: by -0.01 points between 1998 and 2003, by -0.05 points between 2003 and 2008, and by -0.13 points between 2008 and 2013. This trend is not evenly spread over the 24 countries. Over the period 1998–2013, five countries raised their dismissal costs, namely Ireland (+0.19), Germany (+0.14), the Netherlands (+0.04), Belgium (+0.03), and France (+0.03). On the contrary, other countries substantially reduced employment protection: the largest reform was in Portugal (-1.28), followed by the Slovak Republic (-0.63), Greece (-0.48), and Spain (-0.40).

Figure 5

Labor market reforms between 1998 and 2013 (change in the EPL OECD index).

Note: Estonia, Luxembourg, Slovenia, and Iceland are not presented in the graph since data on their EPL are available only over the period 2003–2013.

Source: OECD. EPL, employment protection legislation.

The indicators for three types of EPL weakened over the period. The largest reduction in the index is observed for temporary contracts, with a decrease of 0.23, and it was also the lowest indicator at 1.71 in 2013. Individual dismissals were on average less costly in 2013 than in 1998 with a reduction in the indicator by 0.22 points to reach a score of 2.18 in 2013. Employment protection in the event of collective redundancies remains high at 3.15 in 2013 (-0.15 points compared to 1998). A high degree of protection of individual dismissals is not always associated with a high protection of collective redundancies and vice versa. For example, Belgium had in 2013 the highest index of collective EPL at 5.12 but a low score (well below the European average) for individual dismissals (1.81). On the contrary, Portugal had the highest score of individual protection (3.18) but was among the lowest score for collective redundancies (1.87).

A high level of regulation in product and labor markets is not always associated with a high unemployment rate (Figure 6). Germany, for instance, had the third lowest unemployment rate in 2013, while its level of employment protection was the highest. In terms of regulation in the product market, Switzerland was the fifth most highly regulated country but had the second lowest unemployment rate. There are also some counterexamples. The highest unemployment rate was found in Greece, which has the most highly regulated product market. Portugal also had a high unemployment rate (third rank) together with a high level of employment protection (fifth rank). Differences in unemployment rates can thus reflect institutional and economic features, but are also impacted by macroeconomic shocks. Countries with high unemployment rates tend to be countries which were more affected by the economic crisis.

Figure 6

Relationship between unemployment rate and regulatory indices (2013).

Source: EC, OECD.

A bivariate analysis of the regulatory indices with respect to unemployment rates shows a slightly negative correlation (-0.03) between employment protection and unemployment in 2013 and a slightly positive correlation (0.03) in 1998. The relationship between PMR and unemployment is always positive with a correlation of 0.28 in 1998 and 0.32 in 2013.

Empirical results

To explore the institutional determinants of unemployment, in particular PMR and EPL, we first estimate the following equation:

uit=β0+β1PMRit+β2EPLit+β3Xit+β4Zit+γt+eit$${{u}_{it}}={{\beta }_{0}}+{{\beta }_{1}}\text{PM}{{\text{R}}_{it}}+{{\beta }_{2}}\text{EP}{{\text{L}}_{it}}+{{\beta }_{3}}{{X}_{it}}+{{\beta }_{4}}{{Z}_{it}}+{{\gamma }_{t}}+{{\text{e}}_{it}}$$

where u is the unemployment rate in country i and year t; PMR represents the PMR indicator; EPL is the EPL index; X groups control variables for other labor market policies (net replacement rate and union density); Z is a vector of control variables for macroeconomic factors (GDP gap, inflation, and labor productivity); gt is a time fixed effect and eit is the error term.

Control variables have been chosen depending on the availability of the data and based on previous research. Together with EPL, union density and the replacement rate are important factors for the unemployment rate. Higher union density raises the bargaining power of workers, hence increases wages which in turn reduces the number of workers hired and thus increases the unemployment rate (Nickell and Andrews, 1983). The replacement rate (unemployment benefits received when not working relative to wages earned when employed) can also directly influence unemployment. Higher unemployment benefits put upward pressure on bargained wages and hence lower the equilibrium level of employment (Cahuc and Zylberberg 1996). This finding is largely confirmed by empirical literature (Brauninger 2000, Meyer 1980, Adams and Coe 1990, Calmfors 1990, Acemoglu and Shimer 2000, Holmlund 1998) even if a high degree of uncertainty remains regarding the magnitude of the effect. Macroeconomic indicators constitute a second set of factors which can explain variation in the unemployment rate: inflation through the Phillips curve, the output gap, and a time fixed effect to account for the impact of the business cycle and labor productivity growth.

Estimating and testing a model using ordinary least squares (OLS) involve some issues related to the use of time series cross-section data. Our data are characterized by a limited number of countries and a restricted period of estimation, which makes standard panel data estimation procedures problematic. By simply applying pooled ordinary least squares method, the coefficient variability can be underestimated by 50% or more (Beck and Katz 1995). To deal with standard error overconfidence, they propose a new estimation method: the panel-corrected standard errors. By applying OLS with modified standard errors, panel-corrected standard errors take into account panel heteroscedasticity and contemporaneous correlation of the error terms. This methodology is thus applied to our standard regression.

Some heterogeneity across countries can be omitted or not fully captured by our explanatory variables. To control for this potential bias and to account for the specific characteristics of countries, all variables are estimated in difference with respect to the country mean (country fixed-effect regression).

(uitu¯i)=β0+β0(PMRitPMR¯i)+β2(EPLitEPL¯i)+β3(XitX¯i)+β4(ZitZ¯i)+(εitε¯i)+γt$$\begin{align} & \left( {{u}_{it}}-{{\overline{u}}_{i}} \right)={{\beta }_{0}}+{{\beta }_{0}}\left( PM{{R}_{it}}-{{\overline{PMR}}_{i}} \right)+{{\beta }_{2}}\left( EP{{L}_{it}}-{{\overline{EPL}}_{i}} \right)+{{\beta }_{3}}\left( {{X}_{it}}-{{\overline{X}}_{i}} \right) \\ & \,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,+{{\beta }_{4}}\left( {{Z}_{it}}-{{\overline{Z}}_{i}} \right)+\left( {{\varepsilon }_{it}}-{{\overline{\varepsilon }}_{i}} \right)+{{\gamma }_{t}} \\ \end{align}$$

Potential endogeneity of product market and labor market reforms constitutes another estimation issue. In fact, the effects of structural reforms may be endogenous to the economic environment in which reforms are conducted. Usually, in such cases, an instrumental variable regression is estimated, using the lagged values of the endogenous variables as instruments. To specify the optimal number of lags, a weak identification test (Cragg–Donald Wald F-stat) and an overidentification test (Hansen J-stat) are conducted. The tests suggest that a lag of 2 years can be used.

Different lags, from 1 to 5 years, have been estimated for the IV regression. All specifications provide similar results. Coefficients of EPL and PMR remain statistically significant and of the same sign. Moreover, the evidence of no endogeneity remains for all estimations, even for the exactly identified model (lag of 1 year). The complete results are given in Table S1.

Depending on when the structural reform is implemented, the estimated impact can be biased. For example, the effect on the unemployment rate of a reform conducted shortly before an economic recovery is difficult to distinguish from the effect of the recovery itself. In this case, endogeneity induces an upward bias of the estimates. The contrary is true if the reform is implemented shortly before a downturn. Interestingly, the endogeneity tests contradict the assumption that effects of structural reforms are endogenous to the economic environment (the p-value is above the 0.10 bound). This finding is in line with Bassanini and Duval (2009) and Fiori et al. (2007) who also find no evidence of reverse causality from unemployment to institutions. This absence of endogeneity could be explained by the fact that the regression estimates the impact of EPL and PMR level in year t on the level of unemployment rate on year t. Since structural reforms can take time to be implemented, it is reasonable to assume that the unemployment rate does not influence the current level of regulation in product and labor markets. In this case, the fixed-effect regression is unbiased by the business cycle and thus constitutes the best estimation that can be made. Since specifications for different types of regulations and different types of workers do not provide different results regarding the endogeneity issue, the analysis presented in the next sections focuses on the fixed-effect regressions.

Baseline regressions

The baseline regression using year and country fixed effects provides a positive coefficient for PMR equal to 3.45 (Table 2, column 3). Any deregulation in the product market thus implies a reduction in the unemployment rate. More precisely, a drop in the PMR index by 1 standard deviation (0.45) is associated with a predicted drop of 1.5 percentage points of the unemployment rate. The magnitude of the effect seems particularly high. Nevertheless, descriptive statistics

See Table S2.

show that the average level of product market reforms over the period 1998–2013 corresponds to a decrease in the PMR index by 0.29. The associated impact is therefore a reduction of 1 percentage point of the unemployment rate. In the more recent period, deregulation was slowed down by a fall of just 0.14 in the PMR index between 2008 and 2013. Further deregulation of the same extent as between 2008 and 2013 will then be associated with a reduction in the unemployment rate by 0.5 percentage point.

Impact of EPL and PMR on the unemployment rate

(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Employment protection0.97*-1.37***-6.56***-6.36***-5.96**-6.68**
(0.52)(0.37)(1.30)(2.06)(2.57)(2.75)
PMR3.38***6.05***3.45***3.97***3.29***3.89***
(0.93)(0.57)(0.93)(1.19)(1.01)(1.18)
EstimatorOLSOLSFEIV-FEIV-FEIV-FE
Control variablesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Country fixed effectsNoNoYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsNoYesYesYesYesYes
PMR endogeneityNoNoNoYesNoYes
EPL endogeneityNoNoNoNoYesYes
Adjusted R20.830.880.350.390.440.45
Number of observations317317317281279277
Weak identification test327.17137.3469.02
Overidentification test0.300.840.60
Endogeneity test0.190.950.42

Note: (Standard errors), **significant at 95%, ***significant at 99%.

EPL, employment protection legislation; PMR, product market regulation.

By contrast, deregulation of the labor market measured by a reduction in the EPL index by 1 standard deviation (0.46) was associated with a predicted increase in the unemployment rate by 3.1 percentage points. When we consider the average level of deregulation (a decrease of 0.06 of the EPL index), the predicted unemployment rate should increase by 0.4 percentage point. Between 2008 and 2013, the EPL index fell on average by 0.13 point which is associated with a predicted increase in the unemployment rate by 0.9 percentage point. Deregulation in the labor market took place in the very last period of our sample, so that the estimated impact could be a short-run effect of deregulation. This result is in line with the findings of Cacciatore et al. (2016) and Bordon et al. (2016) who show that deregulating the labor market could be detrimental to unemployment in the short run while a positive impact (i.e., a reduction in the unemployment rate) occurs only in the long run. This result could have an incidence on the decision of policymakers to implement or not a labor market reform. Usually, as they have a defined mandate of few years, they will be less inclined to implement labor market reforms. This statement could explain why we do not observe a clear trend in deregulation for the labor market.

To test this hypothesis, we excluded from the sample countries which implemented the largest labor market reforms at the end of the period, namely Portugal, Greece, Spain, and Italy (Table 3). Although the coefficient of PMR remains the same, even if slightly lower, the effect of employment protection on the unemployment rate is reversed, that is, deregulating the labor market is now beneficial to reduce the unemployment rate. As this specification should better capture the long-run effect of labor market deregulation, results confirm the hypothesis of a negative short-run effect but a positive long-run effect.

Robustness checks of the impact of EPL and PMR on the unemployment rate

Baseline regressionExcluding PT, GR, ES, and ITBaseline regression with interaction termExcluding PT, GR, ES, and IT and adding interaction term
Employment protection-6.56***4.21***-5.91***4.18***
(1.30)(1.59)(1.34)(1.61)
PMR3.45***2.83***3.53***2.82***
(0.93)(0.78)(0.93)(0.78)
EPL × PMR6.68**-0.60
(3.36)(4.59)
EstimatorFEFEFEFE
Country fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYes
Adjusted R20.350.280.360.28
Number of observations317254317254

Note: (Standard errors), **significant at 95%, ***significant at 99%.

EPL, employment protection legislation; ES, Spain; GR, Greece; IT, Italy; PMR, product market regulation; PT, Portugal..

Another potential explanation of the negative relationship between EPL and the unemployment rate is interaction between labor market and PMR. Most countries deregulated their product markets, which led to a low PMR index, ranging from 0.91 (the Netherlands) to 1.74 (Greece) in 2013. According to Amable et al. (2011), with low levels of PMR, employment protection yields a positive and statistically significant effect on employment (and thus potentially a reduction in the unemployment rate). Other papers (Fiori et al. 2007, Nicoletti and Scarpetta 2005, Griffith et al. 2007) show similar results. Reducing PMR is more beneficial in terms of employment when the labor market is highly regulated. Adding an interaction term in our baseline regression confirms results provided by Amable et al. (2011): deregulating the labor market is detrimental to unemployment only when PMR level is already low. However, as long as we exclude Portugal, Greece, Spain, and Italy from the regression, there is no longer statistically significant impact for the interaction term, while the individual effects of EPL and PMR remain. The estimated interaction between both types of deregulation could then also be a short-run effect rather than a long-run effect.

Regressions by type of PMR

The positive and statistically significant coefficient of PMR can hide opposite effects. As shown in Table 4, the regressions taking the three types of PMR into account support this statement. Government interventions through public ownership and involvement in business operations do not appear to be detrimental to the unemployment rate. A decrease in state control by the average level of reform observed during the period (-0.32) is associated with a predicted rise in the unemployment rate by 0.6 percentage point. This effect seems to come from price controls and command and controls rather than public ownership. Although the literature on this topic is contradicting, some papers also find state controls to be beneficial to employment (Fiori et al. 2007) or statistically insignificant (Boeri et al. 2000, Berger and Danninger 2007).

Impact of different types of PMR on the unemployment rate

(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)(10)(11)(12)
Employment protection1.39*-0.60-6.16***-5.85***-6.30*-7.67*0.15-1.98***-6.21***-6.12***-7.20***-8.32*
(0.54)(0.67)(1.23)(1.92)(2.36)(2.52)(0.50)(0.27)(1.24)(1.89)(2.37)(2.52)
PMR
1) State control-0.14 (0.64)0.67 (0.46)-1.74* (0.54)-2.87* (0.76)-1.48** (0.61)-2.35* (0.75)
a) Public ownership0.25-0.31-0.14-0.640.12-0.30
(0.25)(0.30)(0.39)(0.43)(0.38)(0.48)
b) Price controls and C&C0.340.88**-2.20***-2.78***-2.06***-2.58***
(0.62)(0.45)(0.46)(0.67)(0.54)(0.68)
2) Barriers to entrepreneurship3.15***4.64***3.91***4.68***3.16***3.97***
(0.40)(0.45)(0.72)(1.04)(0.83)(0.98)
a) Regulatory and admin opacity1 18***1 14***1 43***1 64***1 15***1 33***
(0.15)(0.15)(0.29)(0.46)(0.32)(0.43)
b) Administrative burdens on startups2.92***3.26***2.24***2.80***1.72***2.31***
(0.34)(0.31)(0.56)(0.66)(0.62)(0.67)
c) Barriers to competition-2.80***-0.58*0.480.750.710.92
(0.51)(0.31)(0.57)(0.65)(0.50)(0.65)
3) Barriers to trade and investment-0.460.801.53*2.33*1.75*2.52*
(0.75)(1.07)(0.47)(0.94)(0.60)(0.89)
a) Barriers to FDI-0.45-0.741.89*1.641.551.83
(0.90)(0.87)(1.10)(1.36)(1.00)(1.36)
b) Regulatory barriers0.401.12**0.290.840.440.85
(0.39)(0.47)(0.38)(0.58)(0.38)(0.54)
EstimatorOLSOLSFEIV-FEIV-FEIV-FEOLSOLSFEIV-FEIV-FEIV-FE
Control variablesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Country fixed effectsNoNoYesYesYesYesNoNoYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsNoYesYesYesYesYesNoYesYesYesYesYes
PMR endogeneityNoNoNoYesNoYesNoNoNoYesNoYes
EPL endogeneityNoNoNoNoYesYesNoNoNoNoYesYes
Adjusted R20.830.880.430.450.500.480.870.900.450.480.520.51
Number of observations317317317281279277317317317281279277
Weak identification test63.52141.9133.4420.19137.3314.46
Overidentification test0.140.860.170.350.880.45
Endogeneity test0.340.720.370.520.470.29

Note: (Standard errors), *significant at 90%, "significant at 95%, ***significant at 99%.

C&C, command and control; EPL, employment protection legislation; PMR, product market regulation.

The other two components of PMR have a positive coefficient. A reduction in barriers to entrepreneurship (average level of reform of -0.36 over the period) is associated with a statistically significant reduction in the predicted unemployment rate by 1.4 percentage point. Simplifying regulatory procedures and reducing administrative burdens on startups have a larger effect than reducing the protection of incumbents (e.g., by removing legal barriers, antitrust exemptions, and other barriers to entry). Barriers to trade and investment also have a positive but smaller coefficient. A drop by 0.18 (the average level of reform over the period) is associated with a decline in the predicted unemployment rate by 0.3 percentage point.

Regressions by type of EPL

The EPL can be divided by types of contract (regular or temporary). For regular contracts, employment protection can refer to individual or collective dismissal costs. We estimate the specified unemployment equation for the three types of EPL. Results are presented in Table 5. Although the aggregate EPL index has a negative coefficient, the subdivision shows that this is only reflected in individual dismissal costs and regulation on temporary contracts. The largest effect occurs for individual dismissals. Less stringent protection (a fall in the index by on average 0.08) is associated with an increase in the predicted unemployment rate by 0.7 percentage point.

Impact of different types of EPL on the unemployment rate

(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Employment protection
1) Individual dismissals-0.00-1.14***-8.52***-8.30***-10.09***-10.27***
(0.29)(0.28)(1.22)(1.72)(2.13)(2.25)
2) Collective dismissals1.31***0.201.62**1.77**3.10***3.08***
(0.28)(0.14)(0.73)(0.87)(1.03)(1.03)
3) Temporary employment0.48***0.47***-1.22***-1.49***-1.60***-1.54***
(0.17)(0.16)(0.35)(0.48)(0.59)(0.59)
PMR2.50***5.25***3.02***2.87***2.22**2.73**
(0.82)(0.63)(0.92)(1.11)(1.04)(1.18)
EstimatorOLSOLSFEIV-FEIV-FEIV-FE
Control variablesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Country fixed effectsNoNoYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsNoYesYesYesYesYes
PMR endogeneityNoNoNoYesNoYes
EPL endogeneityNoNoNoNoYesYes
Adjusted R20.840.880.410.470.500.50
Number of observations312312312278274274
Weak identification test282.1225.6624.57
Overidentification test0.270.460.43
Endogeneity test0.270.180.26

Note: (Standard errors), **significant at 95%, ***significant at 99%.

EPL, employment protection legislation; PMR, product market regulation.

To a lesser extent, a lower rate of regulation in the use of temporary contracts (-0.07 on average) would also raise the unemployment rate by 0.1 percentage point. Regulation of temporary contracts includes rules for fixed-term contracts (valid cases for the use of fixed-term contracts, maximum number of successive fixed-term contracts, and maximum cumulated duration of successive fixed-term contracts) as well as rules for temporary work agency employment (types of work for which temporary work agency employment is legal, restrictions on the number of renewals, maximum cumulated duration, and equal treatment of regular and agency workers at the user firm).

Deregulation in EPL for collective redundancies, on the contrary, appears to reduce unemployment. However, decrease in the rigidity of rules for collective redundancies (such as specific requirements, delays, and costs to employers) has been very limited over the period, meaning that the average level of reform (-0.03) is predicted to have induced only a slightly reduction in the unemployment rate by 0.05 percentage point.

Since aggregate results were different when excluding some countries, we also tested the estimation of subcomponents of EPL without Portugal, Greece, Spain, and Italy. Interestingly, coefficients of individual dismissals and temporary employment become not statistically significant, such that different level of regulation has no incidence on the unemployment rate. The only remaining effect is coming from collective dismissals which keep a positive and highly statistically significant coefficient. In other words, even after controlling for countries which implemented the largest labor market reforms during the period, reducing protection against collective dismissals still remains beneficial to decrease the unemployment rate.

See Table S3

Regressions by types of workers

Based on the unemployment rates for different categories of workers, we estimated the impact of PMR and EPL using fixed-effects regression.

Endogeneity tests also show no evidence of reverse causality for different types of workers. As a result, only the fixed-effect estimation is presented in this section.

Workers are distinguished by gender, age, and educational attainment. Three categories are considered for the age of individuals: 15–24, 25–49, and 50–74 years. Educational levels are provided by degrees and not by years of schooling to facilitate comparison by country and to avoid the possibility of repeated grades. The categories are based on the International Standard Classification of Education (ISCED). The low educational level corresponds to preprimary education, primary education, and lower secondary education (levels 0–2 of the ISCED). Middle education corresponds to upper secondary education and postsecondary non-tertiary education (levels 3–4). Finally, the higher education level corresponds to the first and second stages of tertiary education (levels 5–6).

The results, presented in Table 6, show the effects in similar directions across types of workers. All estimated regressions provide a negative coefficient for EPL, meaning that deregulation raises the unemployment rate and a positive coefficient for PMR which implies that deregulation reduces the unemployment rate. The magnitude of the coefficients differs. Analysis by gender shows a larger effect of structural reforms on women: a reduction by 1 standard deviation of PMR reduces the female unemployment rate by 1.7 percentage points against only 1.5 percentage points for men. In the case of employment protection reforms, a decrease by 1 standard deviation raises the unemployment rate by 3.3 percentage points for women and 2.8 percentage points for men. Nevertheless, for both structural reforms, coefficients for men and women are not statistically different for men and women.

Impact of PMR and EPL on unemployment rate for different types of workers using FE regressions

GenderAgeEducation
FemaleMale15-24(Y)25-49 (M)50-74 (0)LowMiddleHigh
Employment protection-7.02***-6.08***-12.80***-6.91***-6.09***-5.84***-6.33***-5.84***
(1.29)(1.37)(2.74)(1.24)(0.99)(1.81)(1.41)(0.73)
PMR3.76***3.26***4.42**3.19***2.54***5.05***3.50***1.32***
(0.92)(0.98)(1.96)(0.89)(0.71)(1.29)(1.00)(0.52)
EstimatorFEFEFEFEFEFEFEFE
Control variablesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Country fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Adjusted R20.300.400.390.380.410.440.370.44
Number of observations317317317317317314314314
|Coeff| EPL statistically differentF=MM=FY>M* andY>0**M<Y*and M=OO<Y**and O=ML=M and L=HM=L and M=HH=L and H=M
|Coeff| PMR statistically differentF=MM=FY=M and Y=OM=Y and M=OO=Y and O=ML=M and L>H***M=L and M>H*H<L***and H<M*

Note: (Standard errors), *significant at 90%, **significant at 95%, ***significant at 99%.

EPL, employment protection legislation; PMR, product market regulation.

Y = younger workers, M = middle aged workers, O = older workers.

Subdivision of workers by age indicates that the impact of deregulation in EPL on the unemployment rate is larger for young workers. Reduction in the strictness of employment protection increases the unemployment rate by 6 percentage points for 15–24-year-old workers, against 3.2 percentage points for 25–49-year-old workers, and 2.8 percentage points for workers older than 50 years. Although young workers are the most affected, coefficients between the two other age categories are not significantly different. Moreover, no statistical differences are observed in terms of product market deregulation.

The three levels of education are equally impacted by reforms in EPL (the coefficients are not statistically different). Deregulation by 1 standard deviation pushes up the unemployment rate by 2.7 percentage points on average. The effect of product market reforms does not differ between low- and middle-educated individuals either, but is significantly lower for highly educated workers. Although deregulation in product market reduces the unemployment rate by 2.2 for low-educated workers and by 1.6 percentage points for middle-educated people, the unemployment rate falls by only 0.6 percentage points for highly educated workers.

Results on subcomponents of regulation for different types of workers provide similar results as the aggregate effect (Table 7). Moreover, coefficients for all workers and for all subcomponents remain of the same sign than the baseline regression with the total unemployment rate. In terms of gender, the magnitude of the effect is equivalent for all types of regulation except for state control for which the effect is greater among men than among women. However, the difference is significant only at 90%. The decomposition by age shows that results on the aggregate EPL index hold only for individual dismissals and not for collective dismissals and temporary employment. For those two types of regulation, results are not statistically different for the three age categories. In terms of PMR, younger workers are slightly more impacted than older workers for state controls and barriers to trade and investment. Finally, the analysis by level of education shows that results for the aggregate index hide some opposing effects. For individual and collective dismissals, middle-educated workers are significantly more impacted than highly educated workers. On the other hand, regulation on temporary contracts has a higher effect on low-educated workers. Regarding PMR, we see that highly educated workers are significantly less affected by all types of regulation. Although, on the aggregate index, low- and middle-educated workers are equally impacted, the effect of barriers to entrepreneurship seems to slightly affect more low-educated workers than middle-educated workers.

Relationship between the absolute values of the coefficients: Are they statistically different for different types of workers?

GenderAgeEducation
FemaleMale15-24(Y)25-49 (M)50-74 (0)LowMiddleHigh
EPLF=MM=FY>M* and Y>0**M<Y* and M=O0<Y** and 0=ML=M and L=HM=L and M=HH=L and H=M
Individual dismissalsF=MM=FY>M*** and Y>0***M<Y*** and M=O0<Y*** and 0=ML=M and L=HM=LandM>H**H=LandH<M**
Collective dismissalsF=MM=FY=M and Y=OM=YandM=O0=Y and O=ML=M and L=HM=LandM>H**H=LandH<M**
Temporary employmentF=MM=FY=M and Y=OM=YandM=O0=Y and O=ML>M* and L>H**M<L*andM=HH<L**andH=M
PMRF=MM=FY=M and Y=OM=YandM=OO=Y and O=ML=M and L>H***M=LandM>H*H<L***andH<M*
State controlsF<M*M>F*Y=MandY>0*M=YandM=O0<Y* and 0=ML=M and L=HM=LandM>H**H=LandH<M**
Barriers to entrepreneurshipF=MM=FY=M and Y=OM=YandM=OO=Y and O=ML>M*andL>H***M<L*andM>H***H<L***andH<M***
Barriers to trade and investmentF=MM=FY=MandY>0*M=YandM=O0<Y*and0=ML=M and L=HM=LandM>H**H=LandH<M**

Note: (Standard errors), *significant at 90%, "significant at 95%, """significant at 99%.

EPL, employment protection legislation; PMR, product market regulation.

Y = younger workers, M = middle aged workers, 0 = older workers.

Conclusion

This paper provides a robust estimation of the impact of both product and labor market regulations on unemployment using data from 24 European countries over the period 1998–2013. We contribute significantly to the literature by analyzing a longer period of time than previous studies which notably allows us to control for the potential endogeneity of the regulatory variables and to obtain more efficient estimates. We also add to existing evidence by considering subcomponents of product and labor market reforms as well as by analyzing different groups of workers.

Controlling for country fixed effects, endogeneity, and various covariates, results show that product market deregulation overall reduces the unemployment rate. By implementing the average level of the reform that occurred in the period 1998–2013, a country could decrease its unemployment rate (other things being equal) by 1 percentage point. This finding is robust to all specifications and in line with theoretical predictions. The overall positive effect of product market deregulation can be decomposed into the effect of deregulation regarding state controls, barriers to entrepreneurship, and barriers to trade. Although a reduction in barriers to entrepreneurship and trade implies a decline in the unemployment rate, the reverse occurs for state controls. The estimations suggest that reducing government involvement in business operations (such as price controls and command and control policies) tends to push up the unemployment rate.

According to our baseline regressions, labor market deregulation, proxied by the EPL index, is detrimental to unemployment: implementing the average level of the reform that occurred in the period 1998–2013 would increase the unemployment rate (other things being equal) by 0.4 percentage point. However, contrary to what is observed in product markets, the trend in reducing regulations is less strong in labor markets. Deregulation took place in the very last period of the sample, so that the estimated impact could be a short-run effect of deregulation. To test this hypothesis, we excluded countries which implemented the largest employment protection reforms during the last 5 years from the sample. Although the coefficient of PMR remains the same, even if slightly lower, the effect of employment protection on the unemployment rate is reversed and statistically significant. In line with recent empirical and theoretical findings, this result shows that deregulating the labor market could be detrimental to unemployment in the short run while a positive impact (i.e., a reduction in the unemployment rate) occurs only in the long run. Analysis by sub-indicators shows that reducing protection against collective dismissals helps in reducing the unemployment rate. Moreover, this finding remains true even after controlling for countries which implemented the largest labor market reforms.

As regards endogeneity, diagnoses tests contradict the assumption that effects of structural reforms are endogenous to the economic environment. In line with some previous findings, the absence of endogeneity could be explained by the fact that regressions estimate the effect of the regulation level in year t on the level of unemployment rate during the same year. Since structural reforms can take time to be implemented, it is reasonable to assume that the unemployment rate does not influence the current level of regulation in product and labor markets.

This paper also goes further in the analysis by distinguishing unemployed workers by age, gender, and education. For all types of workers, the sign of the coefficients remains the same as for the aggregate unemployment rate, namely positive for PMR and negative for EPL. The magnitude of the impact differs, however. Younger workers (aged between 15 and 24 years) are more impacted by labor market regulations than workers aged 25 years and older. The effect is approximately two times bigger. Analysis by level of education shows a larger effect of product market deregulation on the unemployment rate of low- and middle-educated workers than for highly educated workers. The effect of EPL, however, does not differ by educational attainment. Finally, men and women are almost equally impacted by both types of reforms.

Further research could go in different directions. First of all, this paper only considers the impact on the unemployment rate; it does not provide evidence about the effect on the employment or inactivity rates. A reduction in the unemployment rate can result from either a higher employment rate or a higher inactivity rate (when workers leave the labor force). The data do not make it possible to measure flows into and out of employment and into and out of the labor force. Second, another distinction that could be made in addition to the type of regulation and the type of workers is a sectoral analysis. It could also be interesting to evaluate which sectors are most affected by deregulation and see whether these are the sectors that are creating more jobs.

Supplementary materials

Instrumental variable estimations using different lagged values

Testing PMR endogeneityTesting EPL endogeneityTesting PMR and EPL endogeneity
Lag 1Lag 2Lag 3Lag 4Lag 5Lag 1Lag 2Lag 3Lag 4Lag 5Lag 1Lag 2Lag 3Lag 4Lag 5
Employment protection-6.74***-6.36***-6.35***-6.80***-7.53***-6.43***-5.96**-6.55**-7.26**-8.24**-7.13***-6.68**-7.25**-8.24**-9.47**
(1.90)(2.06)(2.18)(2.30)(2.46)(2.38)(2.57)(3.18)(3.43)(3.56)(2.61)(2.75)(3.31)(3.63)(3.73)
PMR414***3 97***4 25***4 28***4 25**3 14***3 29***3 50***3 10***2 68**4 25***3 89***4 24***417***444**
(1.12)(1.19)(1.33)(1.48)(1.73)(0.97)(1.01)(1.06)(1.15)(1.26)(1.17)(1.18)(1.33)(1.48)(1.80)
EstimatorIV-FEIV-FEIV-FEIV-FEIV-FEIV-FEIV-FEIV-FEIV-FEIV-FEIV-FEIV-FEIV-FEIV-FEIV-FE
Control variablesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
PMR endogeneityYesYesYesYesYesNoNoNoNoNoYesYesYesYesYes
EPL endogeneityNoNoNoNoNoYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Adjusted R20.390.390.390.400.410.410.440.440.450.460.410.450.440.460.47
Number of observations299281263242221298279260238216297277257234211
Weak identification test80.1327.2178.899.456.337.1137.392.056.240.642.669.044.426.116.6
Overidentification test-0.300.240.160.16-0.840.180.310.50-0.600.270.370.54
Endogeneity test0.200.190.170.220.340.990.950.310.450.660.330.420.810.960.94

Note: (Standard errors), *significant at 90%, **significant at 95%, ***significant at 99%.

EPL, employment protection legislation; PMR, product market regulation.

Descriptive statistics

Number of observationsMeanStandard deviationMinimumMaximumAverage variation over the period
Unemployment rate
Total3847.94.21.827.5
By gender
Female3848.54.82.231.4
Male3847.54.21.325.6
By age (years)
15–2438417.99.64.358.3
25–493847.14.01.327.8
50–743735.53.20.820.3
By level of education
Low education37913.78.82.553.3
Middle education3767.94.71.431.2
High education3694.42.61.220.4
EPL
Total3442.60.51.64.1-0.06
Individual dismissals3442.40.71.04.6-0.08
Collective dismissals3443.20.71.65.1-0.03
Temporary employment3381.71.00.34.8-0.07
PMR
Total3541.80.40.93.2-0.29
State control3542.60.61.24.2-0.32
Public ownership3543.00.81.15.0-0.23
Price controls and command and3592.10.90.94.8-0.41
control
Barriers to entrepreneurship3542.20.51.13.4-0.36
Regulatory and administrative opacity3542.50.90.44.5-0.44
Administrative burdens on startups3592.40.71.14.1-0.29
Barriers to competition3541.60.60.63.0-0.36
Barriers to trade and investments3590.60.50.13.1-0.18
Barriers to FDI, tariffs, and discriminatory3590.30.30.01.6-0.09
procedures
Regulatory barriers3591.00.80.24.7-0.27
Control variables
Net replacement rate35239.714.710.974.0
Union density37535.122.26.599.1
GDP gap (%)3820.01.8-10.69.3
Inflation3762.82.3-1.716.3
Labor productivity growth3841.42.4-6.411.4

EPL, employment protection legislation; PMR, product market regulation.

Excluding PT, GR, ES, and IT as robustness check

(1)(2)(1')(2')(1'')(2'')(1''')(2''')
Employment protection-6.56*** (1.30)4.21*** (1.59)-6.16*** (1.23)3.35** (1.49)-6.21*** (1.24)2.76* (1.56)
1) Individual dismissals-8.52*** (1.22)-0.70 (1.48)
2) Collective dismissals1.62** (0.73)4.65*** (0.77)
3) Temporary employment-1.22*** (0.35)-0.51 (0.55)
PMR3.45*** (0.93)2.83*** (0.78)3.02*** (0.92)2.82*** (0.78)
1) State control-1.74*** (0.54)-1.54*** (0.46)
a) Public ownership-0.14(0.39)-0.08(0.32)
b) Price controls and C&C-2.20*** (0.46)-1.63*** (0.44)
2) Barriers to entrepreneurship3.91*** (0.72)3.21*** (0.64)
a) Regulatory and admin opacity1.43*** (0.29)1.29*** (0.24)
b) Administrative burdens on startups2.24*** (0.56)1.88*** (0.58)
c) Barriers to competition0.48 (0.57)-0.68 (0.56)
3) Barriers to trade and investment1.53*** (0.47)1.34*** (0.39)
a) Barriers to FDI1.89* (1.10)0.82 (0.92)
b) Regulatory barriers0.29 (0.38)0.71** (0.34)
EstimatorFEFEFEFEFEFEFEFE
Adjusted R20.350.280.410.330.430.380.450.42
Number of observations317254312249317254317254

Notes: (standard errors), *significant at 90%, ** significant at 95%, ***significant at 99%. Regressions (1) are baseline regressions; regressions (2) are estimations excluding Portugal, Greece, Spain, and Italy.

PMR, product market regulation.